Deriving the Long Run Marginal Cost Curve

econhelp
14 Sept 202208:11

Summary

TLDRThis video explains the derivation of the long-run marginal cost (LRMC) curve, starting with a review of the long-run average cost (LRAC) curve. The LRAC is the lower envelope of a firm's short-run average cost curves, where capital is fixed in the short run but flexible in the long run. The LRMC is derived by tracing marginal costs at different quantities, showing how it is flatter than short-run marginal cost curves due to the firm’s ability to adjust inputs. The LRMC also intersects the LRAC at its minimum, with key insights into their relationship.

Takeaways

  • 📉 The long-run marginal cost curve is derived from understanding the long-run average cost curve.
  • 📊 The long-run average cost curve is the lower envelope of the firm’s short-run average cost curves.
  • 🔄 In the short run, the firm faces a fixed input, typically capital, which leads to different short-run average cost curves depending on the level of capital.
  • 🏗️ In the long run, the firm can choose any level of capital, selecting the one that minimizes production costs for each output level.
  • 📐 The long-run marginal cost for each quantity is derived from the corresponding short-run marginal cost curve.
  • 🔗 The long-run marginal cost curve is created by connecting points from short-run marginal cost curves that correspond to the firm’s chosen level of capital for each output quantity.
  • 📍 The marginal cost always intersects the minimum point of the average cost curves, both in the short run and the long run.
  • 🔄 The long-run marginal cost curve is flatter than the short-run marginal cost curves because the firm has more flexibility in adjusting inputs over time.
  • 📉 The long-run marginal cost curve passes through the minimum point of the long-run average cost curve, following a logic similar to short-run curves.
  • 🔗 The relationship between long-run curves and total cost curves can be better understood with additional diagrams, as mentioned in the video.

Q & A

  • What is the first step in understanding the derivation of the long-run marginal cost (LRMC) curve?

    -The first step is to understand the derivation of the long-run average cost (LRAC) curve, which is shown as the lower envelope of the firm's short-run average cost (SRAC) curves.

  • How is the long-run average cost curve derived?

    -The long-run average cost curve is derived by tracing the lower envelope of all the firm's short-run average cost curves, which correspond to different levels of capital. In the long run, the firm can choose the level of capital that minimizes production costs for each quantity.

  • What does each short-run average cost curve represent?

    -Each short-run average cost curve represents the firm’s average costs when a particular input, such as capital, is fixed at a certain level. These curves differ depending on the level of fixed capital.

  • Why does the long-run average cost curve appear smoother than the short-run average cost curves?

    -The long-run average cost curve is smoother because it is the lower envelope of many short-run average cost curves, each representing different levels of capital. Since the firm can adjust its capital in the long run, this creates a smoother curve.

  • How is the long-run marginal cost (LRMC) curve constructed?

    -The LRMC curve is constructed by tracing the long-run marginal cost for each quantity produced. For each level of output, the corresponding short-run marginal cost (SRMC) curve is used, and the long-run marginal cost is read off from this curve.

  • At what point are the long-run marginal cost and long-run average cost equal?

    -The long-run marginal cost and long-run average cost are equal at the minimum point of the long-run average cost curve. This occurs because marginal cost always intersects the average cost at its minimum.

  • Why is the long-run marginal cost curve flatter than the short-run marginal cost curve?

    -The LRMC curve is flatter than the SRMC curves because, in the long run, the firm has the flexibility to adjust all inputs, such as labor and capital. This allows the firm to choose the most cost-efficient combination of inputs, leading to slower increases in marginal cost compared to the short-run, where some inputs are fixed.

  • What happens to the relationship between marginal cost and average cost when average costs are decreasing?

    -When average costs are decreasing, marginal cost must be lower than average costs. This relationship holds for both short-run and long-run cost curves.

  • What is the significance of the tangency point between the long-run average cost curve and short-run average cost curve?

    -The tangency point indicates the optimal level of capital for a given level of output. At this point, both the short-run and long-run average cost curves are at their minimums, and the marginal cost equals the average cost.

  • Why is the relationship between long-run cost curves and total cost curves important to understand?

    -Understanding the relationship between long-run cost curves and total cost curves helps to see how costs behave as output expands. This can offer insights into cost structures, economies of scale, and production efficiency in the long run.

Outlines

00:00

📈 Derivation of Long Run Average Cost Curve

The first paragraph explains the process of deriving the long run average cost curve. It starts by emphasizing the need to understand the firm's short run average cost curves, which are fixed at different levels of capital. The long run average cost curve is described as the lower envelope of these short run curves, indicating the minimum cost of production for different quantities. The process involves selecting the level of capital that minimizes costs for each quantity produced. The paragraph also mentions that in the long run, the firm can vary all inputs, leading to a smoother long run average cost curve. A longer video on this topic is offered for further details.

05:00

📊 Constructing the Long Run Marginal Cost Curve

The second paragraph focuses on constructing the long run marginal cost curve. It explains that, similar to the long run average cost curve, the marginal cost curve is derived by tracing the lowest points of the short run marginal cost curves at each quantity. The video script illustrates this by showing how to find the marginal cost at specific quantities, such as q star and q prime. It also discusses two key features of the long run marginal cost curve: its flatter shape compared to the short run curves due to the flexibility in input combinations, and its intersection with the minimum point of the long run average cost curve, reflecting the economic principle that marginal cost equals average cost at the minimum point of average cost.

Mindmap

Keywords

💡Long Run Marginal Cost (LRMC)

Long run marginal cost refers to the additional cost incurred by producing one more unit of output in the long run when all inputs are variable. In the video, LRMC is derived by examining how firms choose optimal input levels over different quantities of output, with the ability to adjust factors like capital. The speaker emphasizes that LRMC is flatter than short run marginal cost curves due to the flexibility of input choices in the long run.

💡Long Run Average Cost (LRAC)

Long run average cost represents the average cost of production when all inputs are adjustable. It is derived as the 'lower envelope' of various short run average cost curves, showing the least cost at which any given level of output can be produced in the long run. The video explains that LRAC smooths out as firms adjust inputs like capital over time to minimize costs.

💡Short Run Average Cost (SRAC)

Short run average cost is the average cost of production when at least one input, such as capital, is fixed. The video illustrates this concept by showing how SRAC curves vary depending on the level of capital employed. Multiple SRAC curves exist, corresponding to different fixed levels of capital in the short run.

💡Short Run Marginal Cost (SRMC)

Short run marginal cost is the cost of producing one more unit of output when some inputs are fixed, typically capital. The video contrasts SRMC with LRMC, showing that SRMC curves are steeper due to constraints on input flexibility. These constraints cause SRMC to increase faster than LRMC.

💡Capital

Capital refers to the fixed input in the short run, such as machinery or buildings, that cannot be adjusted immediately. The video uses capital as the primary example of a fixed input that influences both SRAC and SRMC. In the long run, capital becomes a variable input, which helps firms minimize costs and adjust their production levels more efficiently.

💡Lower Envelope

The 'lower envelope' describes how the long run average cost curve is derived as the minimum points of multiple short run average cost curves. The video shows that this lower envelope represents the least costly way for firms to produce each output level, assuming they can adjust inputs like capital in the long run.

💡Cost Minimization

Cost minimization is the process by which firms choose the combination of inputs that allows them to produce a given level of output at the lowest possible cost. The video explains that in the long run, firms can vary both capital and labor to minimize costs, which is reflected in the shape of the LRAC curve.

💡Tangent

In the video, 'tangent' refers to the point where the short run average cost curve touches the long run average cost curve at its minimum. At this point, the short run and long run marginal cost curves are equal, and it represents the most efficient level of production in both the short run and the long run.

💡Marginal Cost and Average Cost Intersection

This concept refers to the fact that marginal cost intersects the average cost curve at its minimum point. In the video, the speaker explains that this is true for both short run and long run curves, meaning that when average costs are minimized, marginal costs must be equal to average costs.

💡Input Flexibility

Input flexibility refers to a firm's ability to adjust its use of inputs, such as capital and labor, over time. The video contrasts input flexibility in the long run, where firms can freely adjust all inputs, with the short run, where some inputs are fixed. This flexibility is key to understanding why long run cost curves tend to be flatter than short run curves.

Highlights

Introduction to deriving the long-run marginal cost curve and its connection with the long-run average cost curve.

Review of the derivation of the long-run average cost curve as the lower envelope of the firm’s short-run average cost curves.

Explanation of how a firm can choose the optimal level of capital in the long run to minimize production costs.

Clarification that the long-run average cost curve is smoother due to the many short-run average cost curves being considered.

Derivation of the long-run marginal cost curve by analyzing short-run marginal cost curves at different quantities.

Key concept: at the minimum point of the long-run average cost curve, the marginal cost equals the average cost.

Visual representation of long-run marginal cost curve points based on short-run marginal cost curves.

The long-run marginal cost curve is flatter than the short-run marginal cost curves due to flexibility in input choices in the long run.

The long-run marginal cost curve passes through the minimum of the long-run average cost curve, as average costs decrease when marginal cost is lower.

The marginal cost curve's behavior explains whether average costs are increasing or decreasing.

Illustration of how firms in the short run are constrained by fixed inputs, but not in the long run.

Emphasis on how firms can adjust capital and labor inputs in the long run to find the most cost-efficient production levels.

The long-run marginal cost curve increases more gradually compared to the short-run marginal cost curve.

Summary of the importance of understanding the relationship between marginal cost and average cost curves for both short-run and long-run decisions.

Mention of additional videos that provide more detailed explanations and alternative diagrams to further understand the relationships between cost curves.

Transcripts

play00:00

hi everyone in this video i'm going to

play00:02

discuss deriving our long run marginal

play00:04

cost curve

play00:06

and really in order to understand the

play00:08

derivation of our long run marginal cost

play00:10

curve we first need to understand the

play00:12

derivation of our long run average cost

play00:14

curve which i've drawn here

play00:16

as the lower envelope of the firm's

play00:18

short run average cost curves

play00:20

because we do need this background the

play00:22

plan in this video is to firstly briefly

play00:25

review the derivation of our long run

play00:27

average cost curve

play00:29

i'm then going to go on to find our

play00:30

long-run marginal cost curve and lastly

play00:33

in the third part of the video i'll

play00:34

discuss two features of the long run

play00:36

marginal cost curve which are good to

play00:38

know

play00:39

if you're already comfortable with

play00:40

deriving the long run average cost curve

play00:43

you can just skip straight to the second

play00:44

part of the video all of these parts are

play00:47

time stamped in the description

play00:50

okay so just really quickly

play00:52

in order to derive our long run average

play00:54

cost curve we first have to recognize

play00:56

that in the short run the firm faces a

play00:58

fixed input to production so usually we

play01:01

say that capital is fixed

play01:03

and this really means that when we draw

play01:05

a single short run average cost curve

play01:07

say something like i have here

play01:10

well this curve shows the firm's average

play01:12

costs when capital is fixed at some

play01:14

level

play01:16

of course there are lots of different

play01:18

levels of capital that the firm could

play01:20

hold in the short run however and it

play01:22

follows that there are many different

play01:23

possible short run average cost curves

play01:26

each of which corresponds to a different

play01:28

level of capital so for illustration

play01:30

i've just drawn

play01:31

five short run average cost curves here

play01:34

and this corresponds to five different

play01:36

levels of capital now in the long run

play01:37

the firm can choose whichever level of

play01:40

capital that they wish

play01:42

and actually the determining factor

play01:45

in this decision is the level of capital

play01:48

that minimizes the cost of production

play01:50

for the firm

play01:52

so to find the long run average cost

play01:54

associated with producing any amount so

play01:56

let's just say q star

play01:58

what we're going to do is we're going to

play01:59

trace a line up

play02:01

and the first curve that we hit well

play02:03

that corresponds to the cheapest

play02:06

possible

play02:07

way available to the firm of producing q

play02:10

star

play02:11

and so that level here will be the long

play02:13

run average cost for producing q star

play02:16

and the level of capital that

play02:18

corresponds to that short run average

play02:20

cost curve will be the level of capital

play02:22

that the firm will choose in the long

play02:24

run if it wants to make q star units

play02:27

if we do the same exercise for all of

play02:29

the possible quantities that the firm

play02:31

could produce we essentially trace out

play02:34

the lower parts of our short run average

play02:36

cost curves hence the idea of the long

play02:39

run average cost curve as being the

play02:41

lower envelope of our short run average

play02:43

cost curves

play02:45

lastly once we recognize that a firm can

play02:47

hold many many different levels of

play02:49

capital and each of those levels of

play02:51

capital would be associated with a

play02:54

unique short run average cost curve so

play02:56

something like what i have here and even

play02:58

more short run average cost curves then

play03:01

once we take the lower envelope here we

play03:03

get a much smoother long run average

play03:05

cost curve which is hopefully familiar

play03:07

to you from your textbooks

play03:09

so that was a very short summary of

play03:11

finding our long run average cost curve

play03:13

i do have a longer video on deriving our

play03:16

long run average cost curve that i'll

play03:17

link to below just in case you need that

play03:20

extra detail

play03:22

in order to find our long run marginal

play03:23

cost curve i'm going to do a very

play03:25

similar thing except i'm going to trace

play03:27

out the long run marginal cost for each

play03:29

quantity

play03:31

so let's take a point let's look at q

play03:33

star again

play03:34

and we know from the derivation of our

play03:36

long run average cost curve that there

play03:38

is an associated short run average cost

play03:40

curve

play03:42

that is set at the level of capital that

play03:44

the firm will choose in the long run if

play03:46

it wants to produce q star

play03:49

but this time i'm also going to add in

play03:51

the short run marginal cost curve that's

play03:53

associated with that short run average

play03:55

cost curve and similar to the short run

play03:57

average cost curve because this short

play03:59

run marginal cost curve is constructed

play04:02

with capital set at the level that

play04:04

minimizes the cost of producing q star

play04:06

so that long run level of capital that

play04:09

the firm will choose if the firm

play04:11

produces q star in the long run well we

play04:14

can read off from that marginal cost

play04:16

curve the long run marginal cost of

play04:18

producing q star so it will be right at

play04:20

this level here and that will be just

play04:22

one point on our long run marginal cost

play04:24

curve and i'll indicate that uh point

play04:26

with a red mark

play04:29

so we can take another point maybe q

play04:31

star star just here and this will get

play04:33

messy so i've taken away those previous

play04:34

curves for q star

play04:36

but what we'll do is we'll add in our

play04:38

short run average and our short run

play04:40

marginal cost curves and again we can

play04:42

read that long run marginal cost just

play04:44

off that short run marginal cost curve

play04:47

just like that and this is how we

play04:49

construct the long run marginal cost

play04:51

curve

play04:52

now there will be a point right here at

play04:54

the minimum of our long run average cost

play04:56

curve let's just call that q prime

play04:58

and at this point the corresponding

play05:00

short run average cost curve will be at

play05:02

a minimum as well so the two curves will

play05:04

actually be a tangent to one another

play05:07

and at this point the marginal cost

play05:09

curves will be actually equal to the

play05:12

average cost curves and this is because

play05:14

marginal cost always intersects the

play05:16

minimum of our average cost and that's

play05:19

true for both the short run and the long

play05:20

run curves

play05:22

and so at this level here well our long

play05:24

run marginal cost for q prime is the

play05:26

same as our long run average cost for q

play05:29

prime let's just do one more point let's

play05:32

think about q prime prime and actually

play05:34

on this side of our long run average

play05:35

cost curve so the right hand side of the

play05:37

curve our marginal cost i can hope you

play05:40

can see is above our average cost so

play05:43

just up here like this and so i hope you

play05:45

can see that there

play05:47

all right so in order to get our long

play05:48

run marginal cost curve we can just

play05:51

connect all of these points and i get

play05:52

something like

play05:53

these red this red line here

play05:57

of course i've only demonstrated this by

play05:59

looking at four points and similar to

play06:01

our long run average cost curve you can

play06:04

imagine that if we find the long run

play06:05

marginal cost associated with every

play06:08

possible quantity that the firm could

play06:10

produce

play06:11

we would get a smoother curve so

play06:12

something like this

play06:14

so that's the derivation of our long run

play06:16

marginal cost now there are two features

play06:18

of our long run marginal cost curve that

play06:20

i would like to point out

play06:22

the first feature is that our long run

play06:23

marginal cost curve is really much

play06:25

flatter than our short run marginal cost

play06:27

curves which are pretty steep like this

play06:30

and this is because in the short run the

play06:32

firm is constrained in its use of

play06:33

capital

play06:35

in the long run if the firm wants to

play06:36

produce one more unit of output

play06:39

well the firm is free to vary the amount

play06:41

of capital or the amount of labor or any

play06:43

of its other inputs that they that they

play06:45

use and so they can choose the cheapest

play06:47

combination of inputs in order to get

play06:49

that additional quantity

play06:52

in the short run the firm doesn't have

play06:54

this freedom it's constrained in its use

play06:56

of capital and as a result the long run

play06:59

marginal cost curve increases at a

play07:01

slower rate in comparison to the short

play07:03

run marginal cost curve and is thus

play07:05

flatter

play07:07

the second feature is one that i

play07:08

mentioned before and that is that the

play07:10

long run marginal cost curve will go

play07:12

through the minimum of our long run

play07:14

average cost curve

play07:15

and to explain this we can refer to our

play07:17

usual explanation that we invoke in the

play07:19

case of our short run cost curves and

play07:22

that is well if average costs are

play07:24

decreasing then marginal cost must be

play07:26

lower than average costs if average

play07:27

costs are increasing then marginal cost

play07:29

must be above average costs i do have

play07:32

another video on that logic and i'll

play07:34

link to it below

play07:35

the video is on the short run case but

play07:37

the logic is the same in both the short

play07:39

and the long run so it will still be

play07:41

useful for you if you need it

play07:44

all right that's it there is one other

play07:46

video on this stuff that i did want to

play07:48

do which includes a diagram that links

play07:50

the relationship of our long run curves

play07:52

to

play07:54

the firm's total cost curve so when i

play07:56

get around to it i'll link to it below

play07:58

it's an alternative way of seeing all

play08:00

these relationships um and so it's

play08:02

pretty neat

play08:03

all right i hope that that did help if

play08:05

it did please like and subscribe thanks

play08:06

to my subscribers so far and i hope you

play08:09

guys are having a lovely day or night

Rate This

5.0 / 5 (0 votes)

Etiquetas Relacionadas
Cost curvesEconomicsMarginal costLong-run costAverage costShort-runProduction costsMicroeconomicsCapital inputFirm decisions
¿Necesitas un resumen en inglés?