Lecture 1: Introduction to 14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics

MIT OpenCourseWare
27 Jun 202429:30

Summary

TLDRIn this introductory lecture to Macroeconomics, Professor Ricardo J. Caballero outlines the course's focus on large-scale economic phenomena like inflation, unemployment, and exchange rates, contrasting it with Microeconomics. He emphasizes the importance of understanding macroeconomic relationships and the role of central banks in managing inflation through interest rates, while also touching on the impact of global events like China's economic policies.

Takeaways

  • 😀 The course 1402, Introduction to Macroeconomics, focuses on large-scale economic issues rather than individual entities like households or firms.
  • 🌟 Macroeconomics is distinct from microeconomics, which studies smaller economic units. Macro looks at the economy as a whole, considering factors like inflation and unemployment rates.
  • 🔍 The relationship between macroeconomics and microeconomics is complex, with macro often requiring simplifications and shortcuts due to the complexity of modeling the entire economy.
  • 📚 The course aims to teach students to understand and interpret macroeconomic data and reports, such as the World Economic Outlook published by the IMF, without delving into overly complex mathematics.
  • 💼 The course will cover current events and their macroeconomic implications, aiming to provide a practical understanding of how macroeconomic principles apply to real-world situations.
  • 📈 The connection between wage growth and inflation is a key topic, with recent trends showing a high correlation between the two, which is a concern for policymakers.
  • 🌐 The impact of macroeconomic policies, such as interest rate adjustments by central banks, is significant and can be observed in various aspects of the economy, including the stock market.
  • 💡 Monetary policy, particularly the setting of interest rates, is a primary tool used by central banks to manage inflation and economic growth.
  • 🌳 The economic recovery from the COVID pandemic has been widespread, but China's strict COVID policies have set it apart, with expectations of a significant economic rebound as these policies change.
  • 🌍 The global economy is interconnected, and changes in one major economy, like China, can have significant ripple effects on other regions, particularly those that are economically linked or dependent on certain commodities.

Q & A

  • What is the primary focus of macroeconomics?

    -Macroeconomics focuses on the study of the economy as a whole, examining large-scale phenomena such as inflation, unemployment rates, and exchange rates, rather than individual households, firms, or industries.

  • How does macroeconomics differ from microeconomics?

    -Microeconomics looks at small-scale economic units like households, firms, or industries, while macroeconomics considers the economy as a whole, focusing on aggregate measures like national income, inflation, and unemployment.

  • What is the significance of the exchange rate in macroeconomics?

    -In macroeconomics, the exchange rate is important as it represents the relative price of two currencies, reflecting the economic health and competitiveness of one country relative to another.

  • Why is it not accurate to consider macroeconomics as simply the sum of many microeconomics?

    -Macroeconomics cannot be reduced to the sum of microeconomics because the interactions and equilibrium aspects of a whole economy are more complex and cannot be fully captured by simply aggregating individual behaviors.

  • What is the role of shortcuts and tricks in macroeconomics?

    -Shortcuts and tricks are used in macroeconomics to simplify complex economic phenomena, making it more manageable to understand and analyze the big picture without getting bogged down in every detail.

  • What is the goal of the course 'Introduction to Macroeconomics'?

    -The goal of the course is to help students understand the essence of macroeconomic relationships, enabling them to read and interpret economic reports like the World Economic Outlook and critically engage with economic news.

  • How does the course plan to integrate current events into the lectures?

    -The course plans to discuss current events, especially those related to macroeconomic phenomena, early in the lectures to help students apply the theoretical concepts they are learning to real-world situations.

  • What is the relationship between wage growth and inflation as discussed in the script?

    -The script suggests that there is a high correlation between wage growth and inflation, indicating that when wages increase significantly, inflation tends to rise as well.

  • Why might a decrease in unemployment lead to an increase in inflation?

    -A decrease in unemployment can lead to an increase in inflation because a lower unemployment rate often indicates a stronger economy with more demand for goods and services, which can drive up prices.

  • What is the primary tool that central banks use to deal with inflation?

    -The primary tool that central banks use to deal with inflation is the adjustment of interest rates, with higher interest rates generally used to cool down an overheating economy.

  • How does the script describe the impact of China's economic policies on the global economy?

    -The script describes China's strict COVID policies as having slowed down its economy, which had a significant impact on global supply chains and commodity prices. The easing of these policies is expected to boost China's economy and potentially affect global inflation.

Outlines

00:00

📚 Introduction to Macroeconomics

Ricardo J. Caballero introduces the course 1402, 'Introduction to Macroeconomics', explaining the difference between macroeconomics and microeconomics. He emphasizes that macroeconomics focuses on large-scale economic issues such as inflation, unemployment rates, and exchange rates, rather than individual prices or specific firms. He also discusses the complexity of macroeconomics and the need for simplifications and shortcuts in analysis, highlighting that the course will focus on understanding the essence of macroeconomic relationships rather than delving into complex mathematical models. The goal is to equip students with the ability to read and critically analyze economic reports and news, such as the World Economic Outlook by the IMF.

05:02

📈 Current Economic Events and Their Implications

Caballero discusses the typical structure of his lectures, which will include a segment on current economic events. He uses examples like wage growth and inflation rates to illustrate how these macroeconomic indicators are interconnected. He explains that wage growth and inflation are highly correlated, and this relationship is a significant concern in the current economic climate. Additionally, he touches on the concept of recessions, highlighting the Great Recession and the COVID recession, and how these economic downturns are characterized by high unemployment rates. The lecture aims to build students' understanding of these concepts by revisiting them as they acquire more tools and definitions throughout the course.

10:02

🌐 Global Economic Recovery and Inflation Concerns

The lecture delves into the global economic recovery post-COVID and the subsequent rise in inflation. Caballero notes that while inflation has recently peaked and is declining, it remains at historically high levels. He discusses the role of central banks in managing inflation through interest rate policies, explaining how lowering interest rates can stimulate economic expansion, while raising them can cool down an overheating economy. The lecture also touches on the impact of the war in Ukraine on energy prices and inflation, particularly in Europe. Caballero emphasizes the widespread nature of the economic challenges faced by different regions of the world, despite the specific drivers of inflation varying by region.

15:03

📉 The Impact of Monetary Policy on Financial Markets

Caballero explores the intersection of macroeconomics and finance, focusing on how monetary policy affects equity values and the stock market. He uses the example of the S&P 500 index to illustrate the impact of interest rate changes on asset values. During the COVID pandemic, the stock market initially crashed due to the anticipated negative impact of the pandemic but later experienced a significant boom, primarily driven by monetary policy. The lecture also discusses the recent decline in equity markets, which can be attributed to the rapid increase in interest rates. Caballero highlights the importance of understanding the relationship between interest rates and asset valuation, as well as the anticipation of central bank actions by financial markets.

20:04

📊 Employment Data and Its Effect on Financial Markets

In this section, Caballero discusses the relationship between employment data, inflation, and financial markets. He uses the example of a recent positive employment report that unexpectedly led to a stock market crash. The explanation lies in the anticipation that the Federal Reserve would react to the strong employment data by raising interest rates further to combat inflation. This expectation of tighter monetary policy led to a sell-off in the stock market. Caballero emphasizes the forward-looking nature of financial markets and their sensitivity to economic data that can influence central bank decisions. He also mentions the high probability of a recession in the US as predicted by professional forecasters, largely due to the Fed's efforts to fight inflation.

25:05

🌏 China's Economic Outlook and Global Impact

Caballero concludes the lecture by discussing China's economic situation and its potential impact on the global economy. He notes that China's strict COVID policies have slowed down its economy, but recent changes in policy are expected to lead to a significant economic boom. This boom could have both positive and negative effects on the global economy. While increased activity in China could boost global growth, it could also exacerbate inflation concerns in countries that are trying to reduce inflation. Caballero highlights the interconnectedness of the global economy and the importance of understanding how changes in one major economy, like China, can affect others. The lecture ends with a preview of the course content, which will involve simple models to explain complex macroeconomic phenomena.

Mindmap

Keywords

💡Macroeconomics

Macroeconomics is the branch of economics that studies the economy as a whole, focusing on large-scale phenomena such as inflation, unemployment, and economic growth. In the video, the professor emphasizes that macroeconomics looks at the 'big picture' rather than individual components like households or firms, which is the focus of microeconomics. The script discusses how macroeconomics deals with concepts like inflation rates and unemployment rates, which are critical for understanding the overall health of an economy.

💡Microeconomics

Microeconomics is the study of individual economic units, such as households and firms, and their interactions within specific markets. The script contrasts macroeconomics with microeconomics by highlighting that microeconomics focuses on smaller, more detailed aspects of the economy, like individual prices and the employment status of specific workers, rather than broader economic indicators.

💡Inflation

Inflation refers to the rate at which the general level of prices for goods and services is rising, and subsequently, purchasing power is falling. In the script, inflation is a central topic, with the professor discussing how it is a major concern in the current economic climate, particularly in the context of the US economy. The script mentions that the normal level of inflation for an economy like the US is around 2%, but current levels are much higher, leading to significant macroeconomic challenges.

💡Unemployment

Unemployment is the number of people who are without jobs and are actively seeking work. The script discusses unemployment rates as a key indicator of economic health, noting that high unemployment is typically a sign of a recession. The professor also mentions that currently, unemployment rates are at historically low levels, which is a positive sign for the economy but also linked to wage growth and inflation.

💡Wage Growth

Wage growth refers to the increase in the average wage or salary of workers over time. In the script, wage growth is highlighted as a significant factor in the economy, particularly in sectors like accommodation and food service. The professor discusses how wage growth is closely tied to inflation, as higher wages can lead to increased costs for businesses, which can then lead to higher prices for consumers.

💡Interest Rate

The interest rate is the percentage at which interest is paid by borrowers and is charged by lenders for the use of money. In the video, the professor explains that central banks use interest rates as a tool to control inflation. Lowering interest rates can stimulate economic growth, while raising them can slow down an overheating economy. The script also discusses how changes in interest rates can have significant impacts on financial markets, such as the stock market.

💡Monetary Policy

Monetary policy refers to the actions of a central bank, aimed at controlling inflation, money supply, and interest rates. In the script, monetary policy is discussed in the context of its effects on the economy, particularly in relation to controlling inflation. The professor mentions how monetary policy can influence asset values and economic growth, and how it is a key tool used by central banks to manage economic conditions.

💡Equity

Equity in the context of finance refers to ownership interests in corporations in the form of shares. The script discusses how equity values, particularly in the form of stock market indices like the S&P 500, are influenced by monetary policy. The professor explains that changes in interest rates can have a significant impact on equity values, as seen in the stock market's reaction to economic news and central bank decisions.

💡Recession

A recession is a period of negative economic growth that lasts for at least two consecutive quarters of a fiscal year. In the script, the professor discusses the possibility of a recession in the US, driven by the Federal Reserve's efforts to combat inflation through interest rate hikes. The script also references the Great Recession and the COVID recession, highlighting how unemployment rates rise during these periods.

💡China's Economic Policy

China's economic policy, as discussed in the script, refers to the strategies and measures implemented by the Chinese government to manage its economy. The professor mentions China's zero-COVID policy, which slowed down their economy significantly. However, with the change in policy, there is an expectation of a significant economic boost, which could have implications for global markets and inflation.

💡Aggregate Demand

Aggregate demand is the total demand for final goods and services in an economy, representing the sum of all goods and services consumed, invested, and government spent. In the script, aggregate demand is mentioned in the context of driving inflation. The professor discusses how an increase in aggregate demand can lead to higher prices, which is a key concern for policymakers trying to manage inflation.

Highlights

Introduction to Macroeconomics course overview and objectives.

Macroeconomics focuses on the economy as a whole, unlike Microeconomics which studies individual components.

Macroeconomics involves studying inflation, unemployment rates, and exchange rates at a macro level.

The course aims to simplify complex macroeconomic concepts and avoid overly complicated mathematics.

Students are encouraged to read and understand economic publications like the World Economic Outlook and financial news critically.

The course will cover current events and their macroeconomic implications, starting with basic tools and definitions.

A correlation between wage growth and inflation is highlighted, indicating a current economic concern.

Unemployment rates and their historical trends are discussed, showing a recent spike and recovery.

The current low unemployment rate and high wage growth are presented as paradoxically problematic for macroeconomic stability.

Inflation rates are discussed, with the current high levels being a significant concern for economies globally.

The role of central banks in managing inflation through interest rate adjustments is explained.

The impact of monetary policy on financial markets, particularly equity values, is discussed.

The anticipation of central bank actions by financial markets and its effect on equity is illustrated with recent examples.

The expectation of a recession in the US due to the Fed's efforts to combat inflation is mentioned.

China's unique economic situation and its potential impact on global markets following changes in COVID policy are discussed.

The importance of China's economic growth for global commodity markets, particularly for Latin America, is highlighted.

The course will use simple models to explain complex macroeconomic phenomena and help students critically analyze economic data.

Transcripts

play00:00

[SQUEAKING]

play00:02

[RUSTLING]

play00:04

[CLICKING]

play00:15

RICARDO J. CABALLERO: OK.

play00:16

Let's start.

play00:19

So hello, everyone.

play00:22

Welcome to 1402, Introduction to Macroeconomics.

play00:28

And I won't teach today.

play00:31

So that's a good news.

play00:32

I will start on Wednesday.

play00:34

So what I want to do today is essentially tell you

play00:36

what macro is about, macroeconomics

play00:39

is about, and also the rules of the game.

play00:44

So what a difference a single letter makes.

play00:48

Many of you must have taken 1401.

play00:50

In fact, some of you may be taking it concurrently,

play00:53

a lecture right before mine.

play00:57

And that's Microeconomics, 1401.

play01:00

This is macroeconomics.

play01:01

And it doesn't take a lot of imagination

play01:03

to realize that this course is about big things.

play01:07

We don't look at small things.

play01:08

That's what micro is about.

play01:10

Micro looks at a household, at a firm, at an industry.

play01:15

In macro we don't do that.

play01:17

We look at the whole economy.

play01:19

We think about the US.

play01:20

We think about China.

play01:22

We don't think about an individual price.

play01:24

We think about inflation, so the rate of change of all prices.

play01:28

We don't think about whether a particular worker

play01:30

is employed or unemployed.

play01:31

We think of whether the rate of unemployment

play01:33

is very high or low, things of that kind.

play01:36

When we look at two countries, we

play01:38

look at the exchange rate, which is the relative price of two

play01:40

currencies, not to individual goods in two

play01:43

different countries, but the whole currency and so on.

play01:45

So that's what macro is about.

play01:48

Now, you could think that macro is nothing else

play01:51

than the sum of lots of micros.

play01:53

After all, that's what an economy is made of.

play01:55

A population, a whole population is

play01:57

made of lots of individuals that can

play01:59

be analyzed with the tools of 1401

play02:01

and the sequence that follows 1401.

play02:05

But that doesn't work.

play02:06

And there are parallels in physics about this and so on.

play02:09

The way you want to study sort of big bodies

play02:11

is different from the way you want

play02:13

to understand the movements of small elements.

play02:16

And that's the case in macro.

play02:18

In macro there's a big line of research

play02:22

that has to do with the micro foundations of macro economics.

play02:26

But even in that case, which is very close to micro,

play02:31

most of the action ended up happening in the non-micro part,

play02:34

in the interactions, in the equilibrium

play02:37

aspects of the system.

play02:39

So it's a much more complicated object.

play02:41

And if you were to build it from the micro,

play02:43

it would be an incredibly complicated object.

play02:45

So one of the things we need to do in macroeconomics

play02:49

is take some shortcuts.

play02:52

That's what makes macro a lot of an art.

play02:54

It's not a science, per se.

play02:56

It's some sort of a science.

play02:58

It has the tools of a science.

play02:59

But it's a lot about shortcuts and tricks

play03:02

and so on to capture the essence of a problem that

play03:04

is very complex if you were to model it

play03:06

in all the gory details.

play03:11

And in this course, we're going to exaggerate on that sense.

play03:15

We're not going to do anything complicated, I promise you that.

play03:18

Some occasionally conceptually things will be complicated.

play03:20

But the math will not be complicated.

play03:24

So we're going to keep things very, very simple.

play03:26

I want to communicate the essence

play03:28

of the big macroeconomic relationships.

play03:31

This is not a PhD course.

play03:33

If you were to take a PhD course in macro,

play03:36

it would be a very mathy type course.

play03:38

In fact, most of the people that do apply in micro in our PhD

play03:42

program complain against macro because they find it too

play03:44

mathy and so on.

play03:46

But that's not going to be the case here.

play03:47

That's not what this course is about.

play03:50

My goal-- so if this is a successful course,

play03:54

it's not that you come out being a researcher in macro

play03:57

out of this.

play03:58

Hopefully you'll have a career eventually

play04:00

and do all the next steps that you need to do that.

play04:02

But I want you to be able to do is

play04:05

to read something like this-- this is a World Economic

play04:07

Outlook.

play04:08

It's a publication that the IMF puts out

play04:11

every six months in which it tells you how it sees the world

play04:14

and where we're heading and so on.

play04:16

No equations there.

play04:18

Lots of tables and stuff like that.

play04:19

I'd like you to be able to read that kind of document

play04:22

very clearly.

play04:24

I would like you to be able to read something in say, the Wall

play04:26

Street Journal and read even critically,

play04:29

sometimes disagreeing with what is in there--

play04:31

Financial Times, The Economist.

play04:33

That's a goal of this course.

play04:34

It's not a lot more than that.

play04:36

It's just that.

play04:37

If you do a summer internship in Wall Street

play04:39

and you work in a macro hedge fund or whatever,

play04:42

this is going to be a good course for that.

play04:44

I mean, this is what traders really know.

play04:46

They don't know a lot more than that.

play04:47

Many traders should know that.

play04:48

They don't.

play04:49

But this does a level of knowledge.

play04:52

If it gets to be very complicated, I'm failing.

play04:55

That's not what I want to do here.

play04:59

The typical lecture-- again, this is not a lecture.

play05:02

The first lecture will be on Wednesday.

play05:04

The typical lecture-- and not in the first part

play05:06

of the course because you're not going

play05:08

to have the tools, the definitions and so on to do it.

play05:11

What I want to do is spend 5 to 10 minutes early on.

play05:17

Again, the first part of the course,

play05:19

we can do that because you don't have the knowledge to do that.

play05:22

But as you start building tools, I

play05:25

want to be able to talk about current events, something that

play05:29

is happening out there that I find interesting

play05:31

or something I received that morning, the morning

play05:36

of the lecture, which I find interesting.

play05:38

And if I think you already have the tools to begin to understand

play05:41

it, I'm going to be repetitive.

play05:43

I'm going to come back two, three, four times

play05:45

to the same topic.

play05:46

Hopefully you'll be more advanced in your knowledge

play05:49

in the later stages and you'll be

play05:51

able to understand it more and more.

play05:53

The typical lecture will have 5 to 10 minutes

play05:55

in which we'll talk about some facts, something

play05:58

that is going on.

play05:59

For example, a picture like this.

play06:01

This I received this morning.

play06:02

I think this came from Goldman, I think, Goldman Sachs.

play06:05

Yes.

play06:06

And what you have in that picture-- again,

play06:09

don't worry about details today--

play06:11

is you have two lines.

play06:13

One of them is a measure of wages, wage growth, compensation

play06:20

to workers.

play06:21

And another one is a measure of inflation.

play06:24

Again, all those definitions will

play06:25

come in the next lecture on inflation.

play06:28

So it's the rate at which--

play06:29

you must have heard about inflation.

play06:31

It's something, prices are rising.

play06:33

And what that picture shows you is that these two series

play06:36

are very highly correlated.

play06:39

So when wage growth is high, inflation tends to be high.

play06:44

And that's a big issue on these days.

play06:45

There's a lot of concern about this stuff.

play06:50

So let me try to explain a little bit what

play06:52

is a concern on these days.

play06:54

Again, if you don't understand anything, doesn't matter.

play06:58

If you don't understand anything I'm

play06:59

saying right now in the last lecture, then it matters.

play07:02

But now it doesn't matter.

play07:04

I'm just trying to give you a flavor of the kind of things

play07:06

we'll be talking about.

play07:08

That picture there, again, a variable

play07:11

that will define in the next lecture, not now,

play07:13

shows you the unemployment rate.

play07:14

You don't need any specific definition

play07:17

to know that to feel, at least get a sense,

play07:20

that, well, if unemployment is high, workers aren't very happy.

play07:23

It's not a good thing to have lots of unemployment.

play07:25

And what that series shows you the shaded areas

play07:28

are recessions in the US.

play07:30

What that series shows you is that typically in recessions,

play07:33

unemployment goes up.

play07:34

So that's one of the features.

play07:36

One of the main features of a recession

play07:37

is that unemployment is high.

play07:40

This episode here, it's called the Great Recession--

play07:45

as a parallel for the Great Depression.

play07:47

The US had the Great Depression in the '30s.

play07:49

This is the Great Recession, the biggest sort

play07:51

of recession outside of the Great Depression in the US.

play07:55

And it's also known as the Global Financial Crisis

play07:58

because this was a recession all around the world.

play08:01

And what you can see is that unemployment went very high.

play08:04

That's a very feature, a telltale sign

play08:07

of a big recession.

play08:09

And then it took a long time.

play08:10

This was in recovering.

play08:13

COVID was a massive shock to the labor market

play08:15

So not surprisingly, unemployment, the unemployment

play08:18

rate spike there.

play08:19

But then it also recover, a lot faster

play08:22

than it recovered from that.

play08:23

And today we have unemployment rates that

play08:26

are at historically low levels.

play08:28

And that's a big issue.

play08:30

The rate of unemployment in the US

play08:32

is at historically low levels--

play08:35

way below what is normal.

play08:38

Forget recessions, obviously way below what is it

play08:41

happens in recessions, but even way below what is normal,

play08:44

what happens during normal times.

play08:49

Closely related to that is wage growth.

play08:53

I have just one measure of wages there, is a series of wage that

play08:59

is particularly--

play09:01

what I'm about to say is particularly sharp,

play09:03

which is the wages of in the accommodation and food service

play09:07

sectors.

play09:08

So wages have been rising very steadily and very fast recently

play09:12

everywhere, particularly in sectors

play09:14

like this, where we have some problems which

play09:16

we call labor supply.

play09:17

But I'll get back to that.

play09:19

So those are two facts.

play09:20

We have unemployment at extremely low levels

play09:23

and we have wage growth at a very fast pace.

play09:27

Now, that sounds wonderful, no?

play09:29

I mean, what else do you want, an economy which is few people

play09:32

unemployed and wages are growing a lot.

play09:37

I mean, if this was micro, this would be fantastic.

play09:40

OK, look the guy is employed and he's getting a high wage.

play09:43

This is great.

play09:45

Well, not so fast for macro.

play09:48

Not so fast because I already showed you in the first picture

play09:51

that I showed you, [INAUDIBLE] there

play09:53

is a connection between wage growth and inflation.

play09:56

And that's what we're experiencing.

play09:58

The normal level of inflation for an economy like the US

play10:01

is around 2%.

play10:02

That's normal.

play10:03

That's what central banks target in an economy like the US

play10:06

in the Euro area.

play10:08

Japan has been dreaming with 2%, but hasn't been able for decades

play10:11

to get it.

play10:12

Although now they are.

play10:15

But they weren't, for a couple of decades, to get to 2%.

play10:17

But that's about-- and we will discuss later in the course

play10:20

why 2% is about right for economies of the size of the US

play10:24

and so on.

play10:26

Obviously in recessions, these things can go low.

play10:29

And that's why in the COVID recessions

play10:32

inflation went to zero, essentially.

play10:35

But then it began to pick up.

play10:36

And it's now at levels, which are unheard of in the US since

play10:41

the '80s.

play10:42

So depending on the particular measure you use of inflation,

play10:46

it's around 6.5% to 8%.

play10:48

That's a level of inflation we have,

play10:50

which is way, way above what is considered

play10:53

a normal or reasonable target for the central banks

play10:57

for inflation.

play10:58

So that's a problem.

play10:59

We have had some good news recently in that inflation

play11:02

clearly peaked already--

play11:04

again, definition of inflation, formal definition of inflation

play11:07

happens in the next lecture.

play11:09

But it already peaked.

play11:11

And it's declining.

play11:11

But it's still a very, very high levels.

play11:14

And that's a problem.

play11:15

That's a big macroeconomic problem.

play11:16

And one of the things we want to understand in this course

play11:19

is, well, what to do about it.

play11:21

How do you deal with that?

play11:22

What do central banks need to do in order to deal with that?

play11:26

Now, I've been talking about the US.

play11:29

But this is not specific to the US.

play11:33

This episode this recovery from COVID

play11:37

is incredibly common across different regions of the world.

play11:41

I mean, you see it everywhere with a few exceptions.

play11:43

And I'm going to talk about one major exception in a minute.

play11:47

But it's widespread.

play11:49

It's a widespread phenomenon that we had high unemployment.

play11:52

Then we had sort of very high--

play11:56

well, I haven't told you that part yet.

play11:58

But then we had sort of low inflation.

play12:00

Then inflation picked up enormously.

play12:02

And now we're all worried about these very high levels

play12:04

of inflation.

play12:05

In fact, if you look at what happened

play12:09

between the Great Recession and the COVID recession,

play12:12

it was pretty normal to have 70% to 80%

play12:15

of the economies in the world having inflation

play12:17

levels at or below 2%.

play12:20

So that's a norm.

play12:21

If they throw you into a country,

play12:23

they drop you into a country, the normal thing would be well,

play12:26

it's about 2%.

play12:27

That's a level of inflation.

play12:28

Obviously, if I dropped you in Argentina,

play12:29

you're going to find a much bigger number, you know,

play12:32

10,000%.

play12:34

But the bulk of the countries were around 2% or so.

play12:39

Today you don't find any country with inflation below 2%.

play12:44

Not even Japan, for years we're in deflation and trying

play12:48

to get sort of above zero.

play12:50

That's all they wanted.

play12:52

Not even in Japan you have inflation below 2% today.

play12:55

So this thing I showed you.

play12:57

And for more or less the same reasons,

play13:00

it's happening everywhere.

play13:02

Not exactly the same factors.

play13:04

It's the same episode, for example,

play13:08

with differences depending on the structure of the economy

play13:11

or in additional shocks.

play13:13

In Europe, for example they had very high inflation.

play13:17

But the problem is not--

play13:18

the origin of the problem, the bulk of the problem

play13:22

is the same as in the US.

play13:25

But at the margin they are different.

play13:27

In Europe, the big driver of inflation,

play13:29

the big recent driver of inflation,

play13:32

is unlike the US, which is aggregate demand, a concept

play13:35

you'll understand later.

play13:36

It's essentially the war in Ukraine.

play13:38

That has increased the price of energy and the price of energy

play13:41

has led to lots of inflation.

play13:43

So there are different reasons.

play13:44

But all of them are sort of different reasons

play13:47

that you add on top of what is a common story, which

play13:50

is that we overheated coming out of the COVID episode

play13:55

and now we're struggling with that.

play14:00

Now, the main tool-- and we're going

play14:01

to talk a lot about in this course--

play14:03

the main tool that central banks have to deal with inflation

play14:06

is the interest rate.

play14:08

So for reasons you'll understand later,

play14:11

although you may have intuition about some of those now,

play14:15

obviously when the central bank lowers the interest rates,

play14:18

then that helps the economy to expand.

play14:22

And when it increases interest rate, then it does the opposite.

play14:25

Rising Interest rate makes mortgages more expensive,

play14:27

make everything more expensive so people tend to consume less.

play14:30

Firms tend to invest less and so on

play14:32

because it's more expensive to invest, to borrow, to do

play14:35

something.

play14:36

And there you see it.

play14:40

I mean, this was the level of the interest rate in the US

play14:43

before COVID.

play14:45

When COVID came, boom.

play14:46

They brought it all the way down.

play14:47

It happens that you can not bring the interest

play14:49

rate a lot lower than zero.

play14:51

That's the reason it stayed close to zero.

play14:53

We're going to talk about that later on.

play14:55

But then eventually they realized

play14:57

that we're behind the curve.

play14:58

Inflation had picked up a lot and the central banks

play15:00

were behind the curve.

play15:02

So they began to hike rates in a hurry.

play15:05

And that's what we have been experiencing for the last year

play15:10

or so, very fast increase in the interest rate.

play15:14

Now, this is, of course, about macroeconomics.

play15:16

But I happen to do a lot of research

play15:17

between macro and finance.

play15:19

So I'm going to put a little bit more of a component of finance

play15:22

into--

play15:24

I think I'm going to do most of that

play15:26

in the last third of the course.

play15:28

But monetary policy has lots of implications for finance,

play15:34

for equity, values, for the stock market,

play15:36

and stuff like that.

play15:38

So what you see here, this line here, is the SPX 500.

play15:46

It's the main index of equity in the US of shares.

play15:51

There are several indices--

play15:52

NASDAQ, S&P, Dow, and so on.

play15:55

This is the main index, the most comprehensive,

play15:58

the one that takes the largest companies,

play16:01

and so on and so forth.

play16:03

And what you can see what happens here

play16:05

is that when COVID happened, the surprise that we had,

play16:09

really a pandemia, then the stock market crash,

play16:13

declined like 30% or something like that at the time.

play16:16

That's interesting facets.

play16:17

I mean, that's one characteristic of equity

play16:21

that I like a lot.

play16:23

Other risky assets, as well, but they anticipate what happens.

play16:28

What happened there is the stock market,

play16:30

the shareholders, realized that something big

play16:33

was-- negative and big-- was happening in front of us.

play16:36

So it was time to sell.

play16:38

And so the equity market collapsed.

play16:40

What happens next is even more interesting

play16:42

for a macro economist, which is this big boom here.

play16:47

There's an enormous boom.

play16:48

The economy here still was at levels of activity

play16:51

below what it had before COVID.

play16:53

But the stock market, the value in the stock market

play16:55

had way exceeded the level we had before the pandemic.

play17:01

And the main driver of that, I've shown that in some papers,

play17:04

the main driver of that is not--

play17:06

I mean people tell lots of stories of Amazon

play17:10

and so on, Tesla, bla, blah, blah.

play17:12

If you look at the aggregate, the main reason for that rise

play17:15

was monetary policy.

play17:16

You can explain all that increase in the equity value

play17:20

in the US of the index-- not the individual shares,

play17:23

of the index--

play17:24

by the effect of interest rates.

play17:26

So monetary policy plays a big role.

play17:29

If you care about finance, well, it

play17:30

plays a huge role in the value of assets.

play17:33

When monetary policy is very loose,

play17:35

that tends to increase the value of assets.

play17:37

And that's one of the mechanisms the central banks

play17:40

use to expand aggregate demand when they want

play17:42

to expand aggregate demand.

play17:43

They want people to feel-- you are in a recession,

play17:45

you want people to feel richer so they spend more and so on

play17:48

and so forth.

play17:50

What happened here?

play17:51

This decline, you can also explain it fully

play17:54

with the hike in interest rate.

play17:55

Remember, I showed you that the interest rate began

play17:57

to rise very rapidly here.

play17:59

Well, last year the equity market in the US

play18:02

and most major equity markets around the world

play18:05

declined by 20% or more.

play18:07

You can explain all that decline simply

play18:09

by increasing the interest rate.

play18:11

So that's another thing we need to understand

play18:12

is why is it that the interest-- why is the interest rate

play18:15

matter so much for something like equity?

play18:17

So when a value assets, and when I see what

play18:19

is the effect of the interest rate,

play18:21

and then we're going to think about, well,

play18:23

why would the central bank worry or not worry about these things,

play18:26

and so on and so forth.

play18:27

But the truth is that financial markets and the central banks

play18:32

interact all the time.

play18:33

I mean, if you are into Wall Street type thing,

play18:38

you are going to be watching every day, every time

play18:41

that the monetary minutes.

play18:42

The minutes of the central banks are released,

play18:44

you're going to be watching because it has a big implication

play18:48

for the value of your equity.

play18:51

Actually, something very interesting of this nature

play18:53

happened last week.

play18:54

On Friday, last Friday, there was

play19:00

a release of payroll numbers.

play19:02

So it's an employment index, employment numbers.

play19:06

And people expected the payroll to increase,

play19:13

so to add nonfarm payroll--

play19:15

we'll talk about these things later--

play19:17

by about 190,000 workers.

play19:21

At 8:30-- well and this, you're seeing here,

play19:24

is the behavior of the same index I showed you before,

play19:27

but the futures, so things you can trade before the market

play19:30

actually opens.

play19:31

The market in the US opens at 9:30 AM.

play19:33

But you can trade futures since Asia times.

play19:38

Anyway, so this is the path.

play19:39

It's all very quiet, tranquil.

play19:40

Everyone is waiting the release of this news at 8:30 AM.

play19:44

At 8:30 AM, great news for the labor market.

play19:51

The actual change in the payroll was not 190k.

play19:55

It was over a 500,000k.

play19:58

So enormous addition of jobs to the economy.

play20:02

And look what happens to the equity market.

play20:04

Boom.

play20:05

It imploded immediately.

play20:07

So this is wonderful news now for the economy-- lots of jobs.

play20:10

The equity market imploded as a result of that.

play20:14

Why do you think that happened?

play20:18

I've already given you a little bit

play20:19

of the ingredients for why, for an answer

play20:22

in the previous slides?

play20:26

The reason I'm showing you this is because in 15 minutes,

play20:31

it summarizes all that I was talking about in the previous 30

play20:34

minutes.

play20:36

Why do you think that happened?

play20:38

This is wonderful news.

play20:40

Why the stock market should crash like 2% from top

play20:44

to bottom as a result of that?

play20:49

AUDIENCE: There's a lot more labor

play20:50

because that gives a lot more supply of that thing,

play20:57

and thus, it decreases price because of high supply.

play21:02

RICARDO J. CABALLERO: No, but--

play21:03

OK, that's an interesting explanation.

play21:09

It's not the one I have in mind.

play21:12

The explanation says, look, that means firms hire lots of people.

play21:16

So the price, that means they're going

play21:18

to be lots of supply of whatever goods they're producing.

play21:21

The price of those goods is going to decline.

play21:22

And that's going to be bad for profits.

play21:24

That's a story you had in mind.

play21:27

Maybe there's some of that.

play21:29

But I'm willing to bet that it's not the main thing.

play21:35

So the only clue I give you is that I already

play21:38

talk about these things five minutes ago.

play21:44

AUDIENCE: Employment is very closely related

play21:48

to inflation rates.

play21:49

[INAUDIBLE] up to 0.81.

play21:51

So this could be a result of expectations

play21:53

of continued high inflation rates.

play21:54

RICARDO J. CABALLERO: OK, you're very close.

play21:56

One step more.

play21:57

Yes.

play21:59

That means that--

play22:01

AUDIENCE: [INAUDIBLE]

play22:03

RICARDO J. CABALLERO: OK, there you are.

play22:05

So what happens?

play22:07

The shareholders wouldn't have done anything

play22:11

if they thought that the Fed would not

play22:13

be able to see this data.

play22:14

But they know that the Fed also sees this data

play22:17

and say, whoa, these guys are going

play22:18

to be worried because the economy is

play22:20

going to keep overheating.

play22:21

They're going to have to hike interest

play22:22

rates even more in order to cool down this economy.

play22:26

I already showed you that what happens in the labor market

play22:28

is very connected to what happens with inflation.

play22:31

The central bank knows that.

play22:33

And now we get this big surprise that means they're not really

play22:36

being able to-- they're not being successful

play22:38

at really slowing down one of the main drivers of inflation.

play22:42

And so financial markets are very forward looking.

play22:45

They say, whoa, this is coming.

play22:46

This only means that financial markets

play22:49

were betting that the Fed was going

play22:52

to begin to cut interest rates in four months more or so.

play22:57

And if you look at what the forwards did there,

play23:00

what the market--

play23:01

you can extract what the market thinks.

play23:03

Right after this, it got immediately pushed out

play23:06

to the end of the year.

play23:08

So it's precise.

play23:09

It's the anticipation that the central bank

play23:11

will have to do something.

play23:12

And so I thought it was very interesting

play23:15

for that point of view.

play23:19

Recessions-- well, look.

play23:21

And these are all very good news.

play23:23

But everyone knows that the Fed needs to cool off the economy.

play23:28

So despite the fact that we're getting good news now,

play23:32

people expect, the majority of people

play23:35

expect a recession in the US for this year.

play23:38

I'm not going to explain this bar graph here.

play23:40

But these are forecasts.

play23:41

These are professional forecasters.

play23:43

And more than half of them--

play23:47

so the median of them thinks that there is a 65% probability

play23:51

that there is a recession in the US this year.

play23:55

And we're going to talk a lot about this

play23:57

and probably we're going to be getting news about this

play24:00

while we're taking the course.

play24:01

So this is going to be a picture that we're

play24:03

going to discuss extensively.

play24:06

And the reason for the recession is nothing else than--

play24:10

The reason you ask this forecast, why do you

play24:13

think we may have a recession?

play24:14

Well, because the Fed is trying to fight inflation.

play24:17

It's going to keep hiking interest rates.

play24:19

And at some point, it may break something.

play24:23

And that's the reason.

play24:25

But all these things you are going

play24:26

to be able to understand very clearly through models.

play24:30

The last thing I want to say before telling you

play24:35

a little bit the rules of the game

play24:37

is that I said before that the story I told you about the US

play24:40

is more or less what is happening all around.

play24:42

I was in Chile a month ago.

play24:46

I'm Chilean.

play24:47

And they have the same story.

play24:49

They start hiking interest rates a little earlier because they

play24:51

had more inflation than the US.

play24:53

But they're going through the same cycle.

play24:57

There's one big economy, the second largest economy

play25:00

in the world, that has not been part of this, which is China.

play25:05

China was very aggressive in the COVID policy,

play25:09

so zero COVID policy.

play25:10

So they really slowed down their economy.

play25:12

That's a consequence.

play25:13

They didn't want to do that.

play25:14

But as a result of a very strict COVID policy,

play25:17

they essentially shut down big parts of the economy

play25:20

for a long time.

play25:21

That, by the way, had big impact in the rest of the world,

play25:24

through the network of production,

play25:26

the chains of production and stuff like that.

play25:28

That was inflationary in itself.

play25:30

That part is dissipating.

play25:33

But for their own economy, for the domestic economy,

play25:36

that really slowed down China, an economy that grew typically

play25:40

at 5 and 1/2 to 6%, a lot higher 15 years ago.

play25:44

We're going to try to understand why later on.

play25:47

But last year, I don't know, it was 3% or less.

play25:51

Numbers in China were difficult to figure it out.

play25:57

They're not equally transparent to other numbers.

play26:00

But in any event, it's very clear

play26:02

that China slowed down a lot.

play26:04

And that policy recently changed.

play26:07

The zero-COVID policy changed.

play26:10

And so there is great expectation

play26:11

that now there is going to be a big boom in China

play26:13

because they are lagging behind.

play26:15

I mean, in the US when COVID began to dissipate,

play26:19

we got a huge boost to growth.

play26:20

And that's part of the reason we got all this inflation is

play26:23

because we had lots of growth coming out of the recession that

play26:26

happened in COVID.

play26:27

And more or less the same is expected in China.

play26:30

And one of the big reasons behind those big bounce backs

play26:34

is when people are desperate.

play26:35

They want to spend on something.

play26:36

They want to go to restaurants and cinemas and stuff like that.

play26:39

And the other one is they have the means to do it

play26:41

because they couldn't spend on anything for a while.

play26:44

And so they can travel and stuff like that.

play26:48

So people expect-- and this is a very large economy

play26:52

that suddenly sort of wakes up.

play26:55

No, that's a big thing for China.

play26:57

But it's also a big thing for the world.

play27:00

What happens in China doesn't stay in China.

play27:02

It's a big giant.

play27:04

So it moves.

play27:05

And for some countries it's very, very important.

play27:07

And this picture here shows you what

play27:08

is the impact on different regions

play27:10

of the world on the growth rate and different regions

play27:13

of the world of an increase by 1% in the rate of growth

play27:17

of China.

play27:22

Obviously all the neighbors benefit a lot.

play27:25

But Latin America benefits even more.

play27:27

Why is that?

play27:28

Well, because Latin America produces

play27:30

lots of commodities and China consumes

play27:33

lots of commodities when it's building and stuff like that.

play27:36

And so that's the reason big impact on Latin America.

play27:38

So this is a piece of good news for the world in the sense

play27:42

that activity will go up.

play27:44

But it's good news on average.

play27:48

But it may be too much of a good thing, as well.

play27:51

Why?

play27:52

Because many economists are going through what

play27:54

we described before.

play27:55

They're trying to bring down inflation.

play27:57

They don't want more demand.

play27:58

They want less for now because we're

play28:00

going to understand that connection later on how

play28:02

demand connects to inflation.

play28:04

But you want less.

play28:05

And now you're going to get this impulse from China, which is

play28:10

going to fuel more inflation.

play28:11

It's OK for China because they don't have an inflation problem.

play28:13

But it may be a problem for many of the countries

play28:16

that are trying to undo the inflationary consequences

play28:22

of the previous expansion, the expansion that followed COVID.

play28:26

OK, anyways.

play28:26

But this is the kind of things we're going to be talking about.

play28:30

I said the course is not going to be mathy,

play28:32

but it's going to be all about models.

play28:34

The next lecture is the most boring lecture

play28:36

of the course I tell you in advance because it's

play28:38

definitions.

play28:39

I need to go through the definitions.

play28:40

At least I get bored.

play28:42

But the rest, there's always little models

play28:45

but it's simple models.

play28:46

OK, but the models are going to try

play28:48

to explain the kind of things I discussed today.

play28:51

So that's what this course is about.

play28:55

Ideally, if we're successful, you're

play28:57

going to be able to read something

play28:58

like the World Economic Outlook, which will have

play29:01

lots of pictures like this.

play29:02

And you're going to be able to write a little equation very

play29:05

simple on the side to try to understand

play29:07

what is going on there, and to catch the mistakes, as well.

play29:10

OK, WEO has less mistakes than the Wall Street Journal,

play29:13

but you will catch mistakes, you'll see,

play29:15

you'll be proud of those.

Rate This

5.0 / 5 (0 votes)

相关标签
MacroeconomicsGlobal FinanceInflationInterest RatesEconomic GrowthUnemploymentMonetary PolicyFinancial MarketsEconomic RecessionChina Economy
您是否需要英文摘要?