2. Preferences and Utility Functions

MIT OpenCourseWare
16 Jul 202041:23

Summary

TLDRIn this economics lecture, Professor Jonathan Gruber delves into the concept of consumer demand, starting with the foundational supply and demand model. He explores the origins of demand curves, linking them to consumer choice based on preferences and utility maximization. Gruber introduces preference assumptions like completeness, transitivity, and nonsatiation, and illustrates consumer preferences using indifference curves. He also explains the mathematical representation of preferences through utility functions, emphasizing the importance of marginal utility and its diminishing nature. The lecture concludes with real-world applications, such as pricing strategies for different sizes of goods in convenience stores, highlighting the impact of diminishing marginal utility on consumer behavior.

Takeaways

  • πŸ“š The lecture introduces the concept of demand curves derived from consumer choices, focusing on utility maximization with given preferences and budget constraints.
  • πŸ›οΈ The foundation of consumer decision-making is based on two components: preferences (what people want) and budget constraints (what they can afford).
  • 🧐 Three key assumptions about preferences are discussed: completeness, transitivity, and nonsatiation, which assumes that more is always better than less.
  • πŸ“ˆ Indifference curves are graphical representations of consumer preferences, showing combinations of goods where consumers are indifferent to choice.
  • πŸ” Indifference curves have properties such as being downward sloping, not crossing, and convex to the origin, reflecting the diminishing marginal rate of substitution.
  • πŸ”’ The mathematical representation of preferences is done through utility functions, which are ordinal, allowing for the ranking of choices based on preference.
  • πŸ“‰ Marginal utility is a key concept, defined as the derivative of the utility function with respect to one good, indicating the benefit from an additional unit of that good.
  • πŸ“Š The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) is introduced as the slope of the indifference curve, showing the rate at which a consumer is willing to trade one good for another.
  • ⬇️ The MRS is shown to diminish as one moves along an indifference curve due to the principle of diminishing marginal utility.
  • πŸͺ Real-world examples of pricing strategies in convenience stores and restaurants are given to illustrate the concept of diminishing marginal utility in action.
  • πŸ’‘ The discussion on bulk purchases and perishable goods highlights the difference in pricing strategies for items with varying rates of utility diminishment over time.

Q & A

  • What is the main topic of discussion in the provided script?

    -The main topic of discussion in the script is the concept of demand curves in economics, specifically focusing on the factors that influence them, such as consumer preferences and utility maximization.

  • What is the 'workhorse model' of economics mentioned in the script?

    -The 'workhorse model' of economics mentioned in the script refers to the supply and demand model, which is a fundamental concept in economics used to explain the interaction between the supply of a resource and the demand for that resource in a market.

  • What are the three steps to understanding consumer demand as outlined in the script?

    -The three steps to understanding consumer demand are: 1) Discussing preferences and how they are modeled, 2) Translating preferences into a utility function which is a mathematical representation of preferences, and 3) Discussing budget constraints that consumers face.

  • What are the three preference assumptions mentioned in the script?

    -The three preference assumptions are completeness, transitivity, and nonsatiation. Completeness means that consumers have preferences over any set of goods they might choose from. Transitivity implies that if a consumer prefers A to B and B to C, they prefer A to C. Nonsatiation assumes that more is always better than less, meaning consumers always want more of a good, ceteris paribus.

  • What is an indifference curve and why is it used in economics?

    -An indifference curve is a graphical representation of consumer preferences where the curve maps out all the combinations of goods that provide the consumer with the same level of satisfaction or utility. It is used in economics to illustrate the different combinations of goods that a consumer would be indifferent towards, meaning they provide equal satisfaction.

  • What does the downward slope of an indifference curve represent?

    -The downward slope of an indifference curve represents the principle of nonsatiation. It indicates that for a consumer to be indifferent between two bundles of goods (one with more of one good and less of another), the additional quantity of the good on the y-axis must be greater than the quantity given up on the x-axis.

  • Why do indifference curves never cross?

    -Indifference curves never cross because crossing curves would violate the principle of transitivity. If two indifference curves crossed, it would imply that a consumer is indifferent between two bundles A and B, and also between B and C, but not between A and C, which contradicts the transitivity assumption.

  • What is the relationship between marginal utility and the slope of an indifference curve?

    -The slope of an indifference curve at any point is equal to the negative ratio of the marginal utility of the good on the x-axis to the marginal utility of the good on the y-axis. This is known as the marginal rate of substitution (MRS), which represents the rate at which a consumer is willing to trade off one good for another while maintaining the same level of satisfaction.

  • Why are indifference curves convex to the origin rather than concave?

    -Indifference curves are convex to the origin because of the principle of diminishing marginal utility. As a consumer consumes more of a good, the additional satisfaction gained from each extra unit decreases, leading to a diminishing marginal rate of substitution (MRS) as one moves along the curve, which results in a convex shape.

  • How does the concept of diminishing marginal utility explain the pricing strategy of different sizes for the same product in stores?

    -The concept of diminishing marginal utility explains the pricing strategy because consumers derive less additional satisfaction from each subsequent unit of a good. Therefore, sellers price larger sizes at a lower incremental cost to reflect the consumer's decreasing willingness to pay for additional units of the same good.

Outlines

00:00

πŸ“š Introduction to Consumer Demand and Utility Maximization

The script begins with an introduction to the economic concept of demand, which is derived from consumer choices. The lecturer, Jonathan Gruber, explains that the demand curve is based on how consumers make decisions, influenced by their preferences and budget constraints. The lecture focuses on the first half of the course, which is about understanding the origins of supply and demand curves. The model of consumer decision-making is based on utility maximization, considering both consumer preferences and their ability to afford certain goods. The lecture is structured in three steps: discussing preferences, translating preferences into utility functions, and understanding budget constraints. The first lecture is about unconstrained choice, akin to winning the lottery, where money is no object, and the focus is on what consumers want without considering cost.

05:03

πŸ›οΈ Preference Assumptions and Graphical Representation

This paragraph delves into the assumptions made about consumer preferences, which include completeness, transitivity, and nonsatiation. Completeness implies that consumers have a preference for any set of goods, transitivity ensures that if a consumer prefers A to B and B to C, they prefer A to C, and nonsatiation suggests that more is always preferred to less. The lecturer then introduces indifference curves as a graphical representation of preferences, using an example of choosing between pizza and cookies. Indifference curves map out all combinations of goods where consumers are indifferent to the choice. The lecture explains the properties of indifference curves, such as their downward slope and the fact that they do not cross, which is tied to the nonsatiation assumption.

10:04

πŸ“‰ Indifference Curves and Marginal Utility

The script continues with a deeper exploration of indifference curves, their properties, and the concept of marginal utility. Marginal utility is the additional satisfaction gained from consuming one more unit of a good, and it is represented as the slope of the indifference curve, known as the marginal rate of substitution (MRS). The MRS indicates the rate at which a consumer is willing to trade one good for another. The lecture highlights that indifference curves are convex to the origin, reflecting the principle of diminishing marginal utility and the diminishing MRS as one moves along the curve. This concept is crucial for understanding consumer behavior and decision-making in economics.

15:06

πŸ“Š The Mathematical Representation of Utility Functions

The paragraph discusses the transition from graphical representation to the mathematical representation of preferences through utility functions. A utility function is a mathematical expression that ranks choices based on an individual's preferences. The script provides an example of a utility function using the square root of the product of the quantities of pizza and cookies. It emphasizes that utility is an ordinal concept, meaning it can only rank choices rather than measure the intensity of preferences. The lecture also introduces the concept of marginal utility and its diminishing nature as more of a good is consumed, which is a key feature of utility functions in economic models.

20:08

πŸ“ The Relationship Between Indifference Curves and Utility Functions

This section of the script explains how indifference curves are derived from utility functions. It defines the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) as the slope of the indifference curve and explains its relationship with the marginal utilities of the goods on the x and y axes. The MRS is always diminishing, reflecting the diminishing marginal utility as more of a good is consumed. The script illustrates this with an example, showing how the MRS changes as one moves along the indifference curve, indicating that consumers become more willing to substitute one good for another as they consume more of one and less of the other.

25:08

πŸͺ Real-World Application of Diminishing Marginal Utility

The script concludes with a real-world application of the concept of diminishing marginal utility, using the example of pricing strategies for different sizes of goods in convenience stores and fast-food restaurants. It explains why larger sizes are priced cheaper in proportion to their size, reflecting the consumer's decreasing desire for additional units of a good. The lecture also touches on the implications of this concept for bulk purchasing and the perishability of goods, highlighting how understanding diminishing marginal utility can explain various market phenomena.

30:11

πŸ€” Engaging Questions on Consumer Behavior and Pricing Strategies

In this final paragraph, the script captures an interactive Q&A session where students ask questions about the implications of diminishing marginal utility on everyday consumer choices. They discuss scenarios such as buying snacks for daily consumption, the pricing of bulk items, and the potential for utility to reset over time. The lecturer addresses these questions, providing insights into packaging efficiencies, perishability, and the nuances of how utility diminishes differently for perishable and nonperishable goods. The discussion wraps up with a humorous anecdote about reusing a refillable soda cup at a baseball game, emphasizing the practical aspects of economic principles in everyday life.

Mindmap

Keywords

πŸ’‘Demand Curve

The demand curve represents the quantity of a product that consumers are willing to purchase at various prices. In the video, the demand curve is discussed as an outcome of consumer choices based on their preferences and budget constraints, highlighting the foundational economic model of supply and demand.

πŸ’‘Utility Maximization

Utility maximization is a consumer behavior theory where consumers make choices to maximize their satisfaction or utility, subject to their budget constraints. The video explains this concept as the core of consumer decision-making, where individuals aim to achieve the highest level of happiness given their preferences and what they can afford.

πŸ’‘Preferences

Preferences refer to the likes and dislikes of individuals, which influence their choices among various goods. The script discusses how preferences are a critical component in the model of consumer behavior, with assumptions of completeness, transitivity, and nonsatiation shaping the understanding of consumer demand.

πŸ’‘Indifference Curves

Indifference curves are graphical representations of combinations of goods among which a consumer is indifferent, meaning they provide the same level of satisfaction. The video uses indifference curves to illustrate consumer preferences, showing how these curves map out the relative rates of trade-offs between two goods.

πŸ’‘Budget Constraint

A budget constraint is the limit on consumption imposed by the amount of money a consumer has to spend. While the initial lecture focuses on unconstrained choices, the script mentions that future lectures will address how budget constraints influence the demand curve by limiting consumer choices to what is affordable.

πŸ’‘Non-satiation

Non-satiation is the economic assumption that more is always preferred to less, given that the next unit of a good provides some positive utility. The script explains this concept as a fundamental preference assumption, where consumers always prefer additional quantities of goods, ceteris paribus.

πŸ’‘Marginal Utility

Marginal utility is the additional satisfaction gained from consuming one more unit of a good. The video describes how marginal utility is a key concept in understanding consumer choices, as it reflects the incremental benefit derived from each additional unit consumed, typically showing a pattern of diminishing returns.

πŸ’‘Diminishing Marginal Utility

Diminishing marginal utility is the principle that as more units of a good are consumed, the additional utility gained from each subsequent unit decreases. The script uses this concept to explain why the marginal utility of a good falls as consumption increases, influencing the shape of the indifference curves.

πŸ’‘Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)

The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) is the rate at which a consumer is willing to trade off one good for another while maintaining the same level of utility. The video explains that MRS is represented by the slope of an indifference curve and diminishes as more of one good and less of another are consumed.

πŸ’‘Convexity to the Origin

Convexity to the origin refers to the property of indifference curves being bowed inwards towards the origin, indicating that the marginal rate of substitution decreases as the consumer moves along the curve. The script discusses this property as a natural outcome of the principle of diminishing marginal utility.

πŸ’‘Price Discrimination

Price discrimination is a pricing strategy where different prices are charged for the same product, often based on the quantity purchased. The script touches on this concept with examples of beverages at fast-food chains, explaining how the price for larger sizes is less proportionally than the increase in quantity, reflecting understanding of consumer diminishing marginal utility.

Highlights

Introduction to the concept of what lies beneath the demand curve and the supply and demand model.

Exploration of the origin of supply and demand curves and the factors influencing them.

Discussion on consumer decision-making through the lens of utility maximization.

Explanation of the two components of the utility maximization model: consumer preferences and budget constraints.

Introduction of the demand curve derived from consumer choices.

Detailed explanation of preference assumptions including completeness, transitivity, and nonsatiation.

Graphical representation of preferences using indifference curves.

Properties of indifference curves: downward sloping, non-crossing, and convex to the origin.

The concept of marginal utility and its role in decision-making.

The principle of diminishing marginal utility and its implications on consumer choices.

Mathematical representation of preferences through utility functions.

Understanding the ordinal nature of utility and its use in ranking choices.

The relationship between marginal rate of substitution (MRS) and utility function.

The impact of diminishing MRS on the convex shape of indifference curves.

Real-world application of utility functions in decision-making, such as job offers.

Discussion on how market pricing strategies reflect understanding of diminishing marginal utility.

Analysis of pricing strategies for different sizes of products in convenience stores and restaurants.

Consideration of packaging costs and efficiencies in bulk purchases versus single-item purchases.

The role of time and perishability in the context of diminishing utility.

Conclusion and anticipation of future discussions on budget constraints and the reality of limited resources.

Transcripts

play00:00

[SQUEAKING] [RUSTLING] [CLICKING]

play00:12

JONATHAN GRUBER: Today we're going

play00:13

to start talking about what's underneath the demand curve.

play00:17

So basically, what we did last time,

play00:19

and what you did in section on Friday

play00:21

is talk about sort of the workhorse

play00:23

model of economics, which is supply and demand model.

play00:26

And we always start the class with that, because that's

play00:28

the model in the course.

play00:30

But I think as any good sort of scientists and inquisitive

play00:33

minds, you're probably immediately asking, well,

play00:35

where do these supply and demand curves come from?

play00:38

They don't just come out of thin air.

play00:40

How do we think about them?

play00:42

Where do they come from?

play00:43

And that's what we'll spend basically the first 1/2

play00:45

of the course going through.

play00:47

And so we're going to start today with the demand curve,

play00:49

and the demand curve is going to come from how

play00:52

consumers make choices, OK?

play00:55

And that will help us drive the demand curve.

play00:57

Then we'll turn next to supply curve, which

play01:00

will come from how firms make production decisions.

play01:04

But let's start with the demand curve,

play01:06

and we're going to start by talking

play01:07

about people's preferences, and then the utility functions, OK?

play01:13

So our model of consumer decision making

play01:16

is going to be a model of utility maximization.

play01:21

That's going to be our fundamental-- remember,

play01:23

this course is all about constrain maximization.

play01:25

Our model today is going to be a model of utility maximization.

play01:28

And this model's going to have two components.

play01:30

There's going to be consumer preferences, which

play01:35

is what people want, and there's going

play01:37

to be a budget constraint, which is what they can afford.

play01:43

And we're going to put these two things together.

play01:45

We're going to maximize people's happiness, or their choice--

play01:49

or their happiness given their preferences,

play01:51

subject to the budget constraint they face.

play01:54

And that's going to be the constraint maximization

play01:56

exercise that actually, through the magic of economics,

play01:59

is going to yield the demand curve,

play02:00

and yield a very sensible demand curve that you'll

play02:03

understand intuitively.

play02:05

Now, so what we're going to do is do this in three steps.

play02:09

Step one-- over the next two lectures.

play02:11

Step one is we'll talk about preferences, how

play02:13

do we model people's tastes.

play02:16

We'll do that today.

play02:18

Step two is we'll talk about how we translate this

play02:20

to utility function, how we mathematically

play02:23

represent people's preferences in utility function.

play02:26

We'll do that today as well.

play02:28

And then next time, we'll talk about the budget constraints

play02:31

that people face.

play02:33

So today, we're going to talk about the max demand.

play02:35

Next time we'll talk about the budget constraint.

play02:38

That means today's lecture is quite fun.

play02:40

Today's lecture is about unconstrained choice.

play02:42

We're not going to worry at all about what you can

play02:44

afford, what anything costs.

play02:46

We're not going to worry about what things cost.

play02:48

We're not going to worry about what you can afford, OK?

play02:50

Today's the lecture where you won the lottery, OK?

play02:53

You won the lottery.

play02:54

Money is no object.

play02:56

How do you think about what you want, OK?

play02:58

Next time, we'll say, well, you didn't win the lottery.

play03:00

In fact, as we learn later in the semester,

play03:02

no one wins the lottery.

play03:03

It's an incredibly bad deal.

play03:06

But next time, we'll impose the budget constraints.

play03:09

But for today, we're just going to ignore that and talk about

play03:12

what do you want, OK?

play03:15

And to start this, we're going to start

play03:17

with a series of preference assumptions.

play03:25

A series-- remember, as I talked about last time,

play03:28

models rely on simplifying assumptions.

play03:30

Otherwise, we could never write down a model.

play03:32

It'll go on forever, OK?

play03:34

And the key question is, are those simplifying

play03:37

assumptions sensible?

play03:39

Do they do violence to reality in a way which makes you not

play03:42

believe the model, or are they roughly

play03:44

consistent with reality in a way that allows

play03:45

you to go on with the model?

play03:47

OK?

play03:48

And we're going to pose three preference assumptions, which

play03:51

I hope will not violate your sense of reasonableness.

play03:54

The first is completeness.

play04:00

What I mean by that is you have preferences

play04:04

over any set of goods you might choose from.

play04:08

You might be indifferent.

play04:09

You might say, "I like A as much as B,"

play04:12

but you can't say, "I don't care," or, "I don't know."

play04:15

You can say, "I don't care."

play04:16

That's indifference.

play04:17

You can't say, "I don't know."

play04:18

You can't literally say, "I don't

play04:19

know how I feel about this."

play04:21

You might say you're indifferent to two things,

play04:23

but you won't say, "I don't know how I feel about something."

play04:26

That's completeness, OK?

play04:29

The second is the assumption we've all become familiar

play04:31

with since kindergarten math, which is transitivity.

play04:38

If you prefer A to B and B to C, you prefer A to C, OK?

play04:44

That's kind of--

play04:46

I'm sure that's pretty clear.

play04:47

You've done this a lot in other classes.

play04:50

So these two are sort of standard assumptions

play04:52

you might make in any math class.

play04:54

The third assumption is the one where the economics comes in,

play04:57

which is the assumption of nonsatiation

play05:02

or the assumption of more is better.

play05:08

In this class, we will assume more

play05:12

is always better than less, OK?

play05:15

We'll assume more is better than less.

play05:17

Now, to be clear, we're not going

play05:19

to say that the next unit makes you

play05:21

equally happy as the last unit.

play05:23

In fact, I'll talk about that in a few minutes.

play05:25

Well, in fact, the next unit makes you less happy.

play05:27

But we will say you always want more,

play05:29

that faced with the chance of more or less,

play05:31

you'll always be happier with more, OK?

play05:34

And that's the nonsatiation assumption, OK?

play05:37

And I'll talk about that some during the lecture,

play05:39

but that's sort of what's going to give our models their power.

play05:42

That's a sort of new economics assumption.

play05:44

That's going to give-- beyond your typical math assumptions--

play05:46

this is going to give our models their power, OK?

play05:49

So that's our assumptions.

play05:51

So armed with those, I want to start

play05:54

with a graphical representation of preferences.

play05:57

I want to graphically represent people's preferences,

play06:00

and I'll do so through something we call indifference curves.

play06:07

Indifference curves, OK?

play06:11

These are-- indifference curves are basically preference maps.

play06:15

Essentially, indifference curves are graphical maps

play06:18

of preferences, OK?

play06:20

So for example, suppose your parents gave you some money

play06:26

to begin the semester, and you spent that money on two things.

play06:29

Your parents are rich.

play06:29

They gave you tons of money.

play06:30

You spent your money on two things, buying pizza

play06:36

or eating cookies, OK?

play06:39

So consider preferences between pizza and cookies.

play06:43

That's your two things you can do.

play06:44

Once again, this is a constrained model.

play06:46

Obviously, in life, you can do a million things with your money.

play06:48

But it turns out, if we consider the contrast between doing

play06:51

two different things with your money,

play06:53

you get a rich set of intuition that you

play06:54

can apply to a much more multi-dimensional decision

play06:57

case.

play06:57

So let's start with a two dimensional decision case.

play07:00

You've got your money.

play07:01

Either you can have pizza or you can have cookies, OK?

play07:04

Now, consider three choices, OK?

play07:06

Choice A is two pizzas and one cookie.

play07:13

Choice B is one pizza and two cookies,

play07:21

and choice C is two pizzas, two cookies.

play07:25

OK, that's the three packages I want to compare.

play07:29

And I am going to assume--

play07:30

and I'll mathematically rationalize in a few minutes--

play07:32

but for now, I'm going to assume you

play07:34

are indifferent between these two packages.

play07:39

I'm going to assume you're equally

play07:40

happy with two slices of pizza and one cookie or two cookies

play07:43

and one slice of pizza, OK?

play07:46

I'm going to assume that.

play07:47

But I'm also going to assume you prefer

play07:50

option C to both of these.

play07:53

In fact, I'm going to assume that,

play07:55

because that is what more is better gives you, OK?

play07:58

So you're indifferent between this.

play07:59

This indifference doesn't come from any property I wrote up.

play08:02

That's an assumption.

play08:03

That's just-- for this case, I'm assuming that.

play08:06

This comes to the third property I wrote up there.

play08:08

You prefer package C because more is always

play08:10

better than less, OK?

play08:13

So now, let's graph your preferences,

play08:15

and we do so in figure 2-1, OK, in the handout.

play08:20

OK, so here's your indifference curve.

play08:24

So we've graphed on the x-axis your number of cookies,

play08:28

on the y-axis slices of pizza, OK?

play08:31

Now, you have-- we've graphed the three choices I laid here,

play08:34

choice A, which is two slices of pizza

play08:37

and one cookie, choice B, which is two cookies and one

play08:41

slice of pizza, and choice C, which is two of both.

play08:44

And I've drawn on this graph your indifference curves.

play08:46

The way your indifference curves looks

play08:48

is there's one indifference curve between A and B,

play08:51

because those are the points among which you're indifferent.

play08:54

So what an indifference curve represents

play08:57

is all combinations of consumption among which

play09:01

you are indifferent.

play09:02

That's why we call it indifference curve.

play09:04

So an indifference curve, which will

play09:05

be sort of one of the big workhorses of this course,

play09:08

an indifference curve represents all combinations along which

play09:12

you are in different.

play09:13

You're indifferent between A and B. Therefore,

play09:15

they lie on the same curve, OK?

play09:19

So that's sort of our preference map, our indifference curves.

play09:23

And these indifference curves are

play09:24

going to have four properties, four properties

play09:28

that you have to--

play09:29

that follow naturally from this--

play09:31

it's really three and 1/2.

play09:32

The third and fourth are really pretty much the same,

play09:35

but I like to write them out as four.

play09:36

Four properties that follow from these underlying assumptions--

play09:41

Property one is, consumers prefer higher indifference

play09:45

curves.

play09:46

Consumers prefer higher indifference curves, OK?

play09:53

And that's just all from more is better.

play09:55

That is, an indifference curve that's higher

play09:57

goes through package that has at least as much of one thing

play10:00

and more of the other thing.

play10:02

Therefore, you prefer it, OK?

play10:04

So as indifference curve shifts out, people are happier, OK?

play10:08

So on that higher indifference curve, point C,

play10:12

you are happier than points A and B,

play10:14

because more is better, OK?

play10:18

The second is that indifference curves never cross.

play10:27

Indifference curves never cross, OK?

play10:32

Actually, that's third, actually.

play10:35

I want to come to that in order.

play10:36

Second-- third is the indifference curves never--

play10:38

Second is indifference curves are downward sloping.

play10:44

Second is indifference curves are downward sloping.

play10:47

Indifference curves are downward sloping.

play10:49

Let's talk about that first, OK?

play10:52

That simply comes from the principle of nonsatiation.

play10:57

So look at figure 2-2.

play10:59

Here's an upward sloping indifference curve, OK?

play11:04

Why does that violate the principle of nonsatiation?

play11:06

Why does that violate that?

play11:07

Yeah.

play11:08

AUDIENCE: Either, if you're-- either you're less happy with

play11:10

you have more cookies, or you're less happy if you have more

play11:14

pizza.

play11:16

And like there's-- and that violates nonsatiation.

play11:20

JONATHAN GRUBER: Exactly.

play11:21

So basically, you're indifferent-- on this curve,

play11:23

you're indifferent with one of each and two of each.

play11:25

You can't be indifferent.

play11:26

Two of each has got to be better than one of each.

play11:28

So an upward sloping indifference curve

play11:30

would violate nonsatiation.

play11:31

So that's the second property of indifference curve.

play11:34

The third property of indifference curve

play11:35

is the indifference curves never cross, OK?

play11:38

We could see that in figure 2-3, OK?

play11:43

Someone else tell me why this violates

play11:44

the properties I wrote up there, indifference curves crossing.

play11:48

Yeah.

play11:49

AUDIENCE: Because B and C [is strictly better.

play11:51

JONATHAN GRUBER: What's that?

play11:52

AUDIENCE: Because B and C, B is strictly better.

play11:54

JONATHAN GRUBER: Because the B and C, B is strictly better.

play11:57

That's right.

play11:57

AUDIENCE: [INAUDIBLE]

play11:59

JONATHAN GRUBER: But they're also

play12:01

both on the same curve as A. So you're

play12:03

saying they're both-- you're indifferent with A for both B

play12:06

and C, but you can't be, because B is strictly better than C.

play12:08

So it violates transitivity, OK?

play12:11

So the problem with crossing indifference curves

play12:13

is they violate transitivity.

play12:17

And then finally, the fourth is sort

play12:20

of a cute extra assumption, but I

play12:22

think it's important to clarify, which

play12:24

is that there is only one indifference

play12:28

curve through every possible consumption bundle,

play12:33

only one IC through every bundle.

play12:42

OK, you can't have two indifference curves going

play12:44

through the same bundle, OK?

play12:47

And that's because of completeness.

play12:49

If you have two indifference curves

play12:49

going through the same bundle, you

play12:51

wouldn't know how you felt, OK?

play12:52

So there can only be one going through every bundle,

play12:54

because you know how you feel.

play12:56

You may feel indifferent, but you know how you feel.

play12:58

You can't say I don't know, OK?

play13:00

So that's sort of a extra assumption

play13:02

that sort of completes the link to the properties, OK?

play13:06

So that's basically how indifference curves work.

play13:10

Now, I find-- when I took this course, before you were--

play13:15

god, maybe before your parents were born,

play13:17

I don't know, certainly before you guys were born--

play13:19

when I took this course, I found this course

play13:21

full of a lot of light bulb moments, that

play13:23

is, stuff was just sort of confusing,

play13:24

and then boom, an example really made it work for me.

play13:26

And the example that made indifference curves work to me

play13:29

was actually doing my first UROP.

play13:31

When my UROP was with a grad student, and that grad student

play13:33

had to decide whether he was going to accept a job.

play13:35

He had a series of job offers, so he had to decide.

play13:38

And basically, he said, "Here's the way I'm thinking about it.

play13:40

I am indifferent-- I have an indifference map

play13:42

and I care about two things.

play13:43

I care about school location and I

play13:48

care about economics department quality.

play13:53

I care about the quality of my colleagues,

play13:55

and the research it's done there, and the location."

play13:57

And basically, he had two offers.

play13:59

One was from Princeton, which he put up here.

play14:02

No offense to New Jerseyans, but Princeton

play14:03

as a young single person sucks.

play14:05

OK, fine when you're married and have kids, but deadly

play14:08

as a young single person.

play14:09

And the other-- so that's Princeton.

play14:11

Down here was Santa Cruz.

play14:13

OK, awesome.

play14:14

[INAUDIBLE] is the most beautiful university

play14:15

in America, OK?

play14:17

But not as good an economics department.

play14:19

And he decided he was roughly indifferent between the two.

play14:23

But he had a third offer from the IMF, which

play14:27

is a research institution in DC, which

play14:29

has-- he had a lot of good colleagues,

play14:30

and DC is way better than Princeton, New Jersey,

play14:32

even though it's not as good as Santa Cruz.

play14:34

So he decided he would take the offer at the IMF, OK?

play14:37

Even though the IMF had worse colleagues than Princeton

play14:41

and worse location than Santa Cruz,

play14:43

it was still better in combination of the two of them,

play14:46

given his preferences.

play14:47

And that's how he used indifference curves

play14:49

to make his decision, OK?

play14:52

So that's sort of an example of applying it.

play14:54

Once again, no offense to the New

play14:56

Jerseyans in the room, of which I am one, but believe me,

play14:59

you'd rather be in Santa Cruz.

play15:01

OK, so now, let's go from preferences

play15:05

to utility functions.

play15:12

OK, so now, we're going to move from preferences, which we've

play15:15

represented graphically, to utility functions, which we're

play15:19

going to represent mathematically.

play15:21

Remember, I want you understand, everything this course

play15:23

at three levels, graphically, mathematically,

play15:25

and most importantly of all, intuitively, OK?

play15:28

So graphic is indifference curves.

play15:30

Now we come to the mathematical representation,

play15:32

which is utility function, OK?

play15:34

And the idea is that every individual, all of you

play15:37

in this room, have a stable, well behaved,

play15:41

underlying mathematical representation

play15:43

of your preferences, which we call utility function.

play15:47

Now, once again, that's going to be very complicated,

play15:50

your preference over lots of different things.

play15:52

We're going to make things simple by writing out

play15:53

a two dimensional representation for now of your indifference

play15:56

curve.

play15:57

We're going to say, how do we act mathematically

play15:59

represent your feelings about pizza versus cookies?

play16:03

OK?

play16:04

Imagine that's all you care about in the world,

play16:06

is pizza and cookies.

play16:07

How do we mathematically represent that?

play16:09

So for example, we could write down

play16:11

that your utility function is equal to the square root

play16:15

of the number of slices of pizza times the number of cookies.

play16:18

We could write that down.

play16:19

I'm not saying that's right.

play16:20

I'm not saying it works for anyone in this room

play16:22

or even everyone this room, but that is a possible way

play16:25

to represent utility, OK?

play16:29

What this would say--

play16:30

this is convenient.

play16:31

We will use-- we'll end up using square root form a lot

play16:33

for utility functions and a lot of convenient mathematical

play16:35

properties.

play16:36

And it happens to jive with our example, right?

play16:39

Because in this example, you're indifferent between two pizza

play16:41

and one cookie or one pizza and two cookie.

play16:44

They're both square root of 2.

play16:45

And you prefer two pizza and two cookies.

play16:47

That's two, OK?

play16:49

So this gives you a high utility for two pizza and two cookies,

play16:53

OK, than one pizza and two cookie,

play16:59

or two pizza and one cookie.

play17:02

So now, the question is, what does this mean?

play17:04

What is utility?

play17:06

Well, utility doesn't actually mean anything.

play17:10

There's not really a thing out there called utiles OK?

play17:14

In other words, utility is not a cardinal concept.

play17:16

It is only an ordinal concept.

play17:19

You cannot say your utility, you are--

play17:23

you cannot literally say, "My utility is x% higher than

play17:26

your utility," but you can rank them.

play17:29

So we're going to assume that utility can be ranked

play17:32

to allow you to rank choices.

play17:34

Even if generally, we might slip some and sort

play17:36

of pretend utility is cardinal for some cute examples,

play17:40

but by and large, we're going to think

play17:41

of utility as purely ordinal.

play17:43

It's just a way to rank your choices.

play17:45

It's just when you have a set of choices

play17:47

out there over many dimensions-- like if your choice in life

play17:49

was always over one dimension and more was better,

play17:52

it would always be easy to rank it, right?

play17:54

You'd never have a problem.

play17:55

Once your choice is over more than one dimension,

play17:58

now if you want to rank them, you

play17:59

need some way to combine them.

play18:01

That's what this function does.

play18:03

It allows you essentially to weight the different elements

play18:05

of your consumption bundle, so you

play18:07

can rank them when it comes time to choose, OK?

play18:12

Now, this is obviously incredibly simple,

play18:15

but it turns out to be amazingly powerful in explaining

play18:18

real world behavior, OK?

play18:21

And so what I want to do today is

play18:23

work with the underlying mathematics of utility,

play18:25

and then we'll come back.

play18:26

We'll see in the next few lectures

play18:28

how it could actually be used to explain decisions.

play18:31

So a key concept we're going to talk about in this class

play18:36

is marginal utility.

play18:38

Marginal utility is just a derivative

play18:39

of the utility function with respect to one of the elements.

play18:43

So the marginal utility for cookies, of cookies,

play18:45

is the utility of the next cookie,

play18:48

given how many cookies you've had.

play18:50

This class is going to be very focused

play18:52

on marginal decision making.

play18:55

In economics, it's all about how you think about the next unit.

play18:58

Turns out, that makes life a ton easier.

play19:00

Turns out, it's way easier to say, "Do you

play19:01

want the next cookie," than to say, "How many cookies do you

play19:04

want?"

play19:05

Because if you want the next cookie,

play19:07

that's sort of a very isolated decision.

play19:09

You say, OK, I had this many cookies.

play19:10

Do I want the next cookie?

play19:12

Whereas before you start eating, if you say,

play19:13

how many cookies do you want, that's

play19:15

sort of a harder, more global decision.

play19:16

So we're going to focus on this stepwise decision making

play19:19

process of do you want the next unit, the next cookie,

play19:22

or the next slice of pizza, OK?

play19:25

And the key feature of utility functions

play19:28

we'll work with throughout the semester

play19:31

is that they will feature diminishing marginal utility.

play19:39

Marginal utility will fall as you have more of a good.

play19:43

The more of a good you've had, the less

play19:45

happiness you'll derive from the next unit, OK?

play19:50

Now, we can see that graphically in figure 2-4.

play19:55

Figure 2-4 graphs on the x-axis the number

play19:58

of cookies holding constant pizza.

play20:01

So let's say you're having two pizza slices,

play20:03

and you want to say, what's my benefit from the next cookie?

play20:07

And on the left axis, violating what I just

play20:10

said like 15 seconds ago, we graph utility.

play20:13

Now, once again, the utile numbers don't mean anything.

play20:15

It's just to give you an ordinal sense.

play20:18

What you see here is that if you have 1 cookie,

play20:21

your utility is 1.4, square root of 2 times 1.

play20:25

If you have 2 cookies, your utility

play20:26

goes up to square root of 4, which is 2.

play20:29

You are happier with 2 cookies, but you

play20:32

are less happy from the second cookie than the first cookie,

play20:36

OK?

play20:37

And you could see that in figure--

play20:39

if you flip back and forth between 2-4 and 2-5,

play20:41

you can see that, OK?

play20:44

The first cookie, going from 0 to 1 cookie,

play20:47

gave you one-- so in this case, we're now

play20:50

graphing the marginal utility.

play20:51

So figure 2-4 is the level of utility,

play20:56

which is not really something you can measure, in fact.

play20:58

Figure 2-5 is something you can measure,

play21:00

which is marginal utility, what's your happiness--

play21:02

and we'll talk about measuring this--

play21:03

from the next cookie.

play21:04

You see, the first cookie gives you a utility increment of 1.4,

play21:13

OK?

play21:13

You go from utility of 0 to utility of 1.4.

play21:17

The next cookie gives you utility increment of 0.59.

play21:21

OK, you go from utility of 1.41 to utility of 2.

play21:25

The next cookie gives utility increment of 0.45,

play21:27

the square root of 3.

play21:29

So now we flip back to the previous page.

play21:31

We're going from the square root of 4,

play21:33

we're going from the square root of 4--

play21:35

I'm sorry-- to the square root of 6.

play21:36

Square root of 6 is only 0.45 more than the square root of 4,

play21:40

and so on.

play21:42

So each additional cookie makes you less and less happy.

play21:46

It makes you happier, it has to, because more is better,

play21:49

but it makes you less and less happy, OK?

play21:52

And this makes sense.

play21:54

Just think about any decision life

play21:56

starting with nothing of something

play21:58

and having the first one, slice of pizza,

play22:00

a cookie, deciding on which movie to go to.

play22:03

The first movie, the one you want to see the most,

play22:07

is going to make you happier than the one you

play22:09

want to see not quite as much.

play22:11

The first cookie when you're hungry

play22:12

will make you happier than the second cookie.

play22:14

The first slice of pizza make you happier--

play22:16

Now, you may be close to indifferent.

play22:18

Maybe the second slice of pizza makes you almost as

play22:20

happy as the first.

play22:21

But the first will make you happier, OK?

play22:24

If you think about--

play22:25

that's really sort of that first step.

play22:26

You were hungry, and that first one makes you feel happier.

play22:29

Now, but you got to remember, you always want more cookies.

play22:33

Now, you might say, "Wait a second.

play22:35

This is stupid.

play22:36

Once I've had 10 cookies, I'm going to barf.

play22:38

The 11th cookie can actually make me worse off,

play22:40

because I don't like barfing."

play22:42

But in economics, we have to remember,

play22:45

you don't have to eat the 11th cookie.

play22:47

You can give it away.

play22:48

So if like say, you don't want the 11th cookie,

play22:50

you can save it for later.

play22:52

You can give it to a friend.

play22:54

So you always want it.

play22:55

In the worst case, you throw it out.

play22:58

It can't make you worse off, it can only make you better off.

play23:01

And that's what our sort of more is better assumption

play23:03

comes from.

play23:04

Obviously, the limit-- you know, if you get a million cookies,

play23:07

your garbage can gets full.

play23:08

You have no friends to give them to.

play23:09

I understand at the limit, these things fall apart, OK?

play23:11

But that's the basic idea of more is better

play23:13

and the basic idea of diminishing marginal utility.

play23:16

OK, any questions about that?

play23:17

Yeah.

play23:18

AUDIENCE: Can the utility function ever be negative?

play23:20

JONATHAN GRUBER: Utility function

play23:22

can never be negative because we have-- well,

play23:24

utility-- once again, utility is not an ordinal concept.

play23:27

You can set up utility functions such

play23:28

that the number is negative.

play23:30

You can set that up.

play23:31

OK, the marginal utility is always positive.

play23:34

You always get some benefit from the next unit.

play23:36

Utility, once again, the measurement's relevant.

play23:38

So it could be negative.

play23:39

You could set it up--

play23:40

I could write my utility function like this,

play23:42

you know, something like that.

play23:43

So it could be negative.

play23:44

That's just a sort of scaling factor.

play23:46

But marginal utility is always positive.

play23:48

You're always happier, or it's non-negative.

play23:51

You're always happier or at least indifferent

play23:52

to getting the next unit.

play23:54

Yeah.

play23:55

AUDIENCE: So when you're looking at 2-5,

play23:56

if you get like a fraction of a cookie,

play23:58

is the marginal utility still going to go up?

play24:02

JONATHAN GRUBER: I'm sorry, you look--

play24:04

figure 2-5-- no, the marginal is going to go down.

play24:06

Each fraction of a cookie, the marginal utility--

play24:08

marginal utility is always diminishing.

play24:09

AUDIENCE: So if you start with zero,

play24:11

and you get 1/2 a cookie based on this graph--

play24:13

JONATHAN GRUBER: Well, it's really hard to do it from zero.

play24:16

That's really tricky.

play24:17

It's sort of much easier to start from one.

play24:19

So corner solutions, we'll talk about corner solutions

play24:21

in this class, they get ugly.

play24:22

Think of it starting from one.

play24:24

Starting with that first cookie, every fraction of a cookie

play24:26

makes you happier, but less and less happy with each fraction.

play24:28

Good question.

play24:29

All right, good questions.

play24:31

All right, so now, let's talk about--

play24:35

let's flip back from the math to the graphics,

play24:39

and talk about where indifference curves come from.

play24:41

I just drew them out.

play24:42

But in fact, indifference curves are

play24:44

the graphical representation of what comes out

play24:46

of utility function, OK?

play24:50

And indeed, the slope of the indifference

play24:51

curve, we're going to call the marginal rate of substitution,

play24:58

the rate essentially at which you're

play24:59

willing to substitute one good for the other.

play25:04

The rate at which you're willing to substitute cookies for pizza

play25:08

is your marginal rate of substitution.

play25:11

And we'll define that as the slope of the indifference

play25:15

curve, delta p over delta c.

play25:18

That is your marginal rate of substitution.

play25:20

Literally, the indifference curve

play25:21

tells you the rate at which you're willing to substitute.

play25:23

You just follow along and say, "Look,

play25:25

I'm willing to give up--"

play25:28

So in other words, if you look at figure 2-6, you say, "Look,

play25:31

I'm indifferent between point A to point B.

play25:36

One slice of pizza--

play25:37

I'm sorry-- one cookie and four slices of pizza

play25:40

is the same to me as two cookies and two slices of pizza."

play25:43

Why is it the same?

play25:44

Because they both give me utility square root of four,

play25:46

right?

play25:47

So given this mathematical--

play25:48

I'm not saying you are.

play25:49

I'm saying, given this mathematical representation,

play25:52

OK, you are indifferent between point A and point

play25:54

B. So what that says-- and what's

play25:56

the slope with the indifference curve?

play25:58

What's the arc slope between point A and point B?

play26:01

The slope is negative 2.

play26:04

So your marginal rate of substitution is negative 2.

play26:07

You are indifferent, OK?

play26:10

You are indifferent between 1, 4 and 2, 2.

play26:14

Therefore, you're willing to substitute or give away

play26:18

two slices of pizza to get one cookie.

play26:22

Delta p delta c is negative 2, OK?

play26:29

Now, it turns out you can define the marginal rate

play26:31

of substitution over any segment of indifference curve,

play26:34

and what's interesting is it changes.

play26:36

It diminishes.

play26:38

Look what happens when we move from two pizzas and two

play26:41

cookies, from point B to point C.

play26:44

Now the marginal rate of substitution

play26:46

is only negative of 1/2.

play26:48

Now I'm only willing to give up one slice of pizza

play26:50

to get two cookies.

play26:52

What's happening?

play26:53

First, I was willing give up two slices of pizza

play26:55

to get one cookie.

play26:57

Now I'm only willing to give up one slice of pizza

play26:59

to get two cookies.

play27:01

What's happening?

play27:02

Yeah.

play27:02

AUDIENCE: You don't want a cookie as much?

play27:03

JONATHAN GRUBER: Because of?

play27:05

AUDIENCE: Diminishing marginal utility.

play27:05

JONATHAN GRUBER: Exactly.

play27:07

Diminishing margin utility has caused

play27:09

the marginal rate of substitution

play27:11

itself to diminish.

play27:12

For those who are really kind of better at math than I am,

play27:15

it turns out technically, mathematically,

play27:17

marginal utility isn't always diminishing.

play27:19

You can draw up cases.

play27:21

MRS is always diminishing.

play27:23

So you can think of marginal as always diminishing.

play27:25

It's fine for this class.

play27:26

When you get to higher level math and economics,

play27:27

you'll see marginal utility doesn't have to diminish.

play27:29

MRS has to diminish, OK?

play27:32

MRS is always diminishing.

play27:35

As you go along the indifference curve,

play27:36

that slope is always falling, OK?

play27:41

So basically, what we can right now

play27:45

is how the MRS relates to utility function.

play27:48

Our first sort of mind-blowing result

play27:50

is that the MRS is equal to the negative

play27:53

of the marginal utility of cookies

play27:56

over the marginal utility of pizza.

play27:59

That's our first key definition.

play28:02

It's equal to the negative of the marginal utility

play28:05

of the good on the x-axis over the marginal utility

play28:07

of the good on the y-axis, OK?

play28:11

Essentially, the marginal rate of substitution

play28:13

tells you how your relative marginal utilities

play28:17

evolve as you move down the indifference curve.

play28:22

When you start at point A, you have lots of pizza

play28:28

and not a lot of cookies.

play28:30

When you have lots of pizza, your marginal utility is small.

play28:37

Here's the key insight.

play28:38

This is the thing which, once again, it's a light bulb thing.

play28:41

If you get this, it'll make your life so much easier.

play28:43

Marginal utilities are negative functions of quantity.

play28:47

The more you have of a thing, the less

play28:50

you want the next unit of it.

play28:53

That's why, for example, cookies is now in the numerator

play28:55

and pizza is in the denominator, flipping from this side, OK?

play28:59

The more you have a good, the less you want it.

play29:02

So start at point A. You have lots of pizza

play29:05

and not a lot of cookies.

play29:07

You don't really want more pizza.

play29:09

You want more cookies.

play29:10

That means the denominator is small.

play29:13

The marginal utility of pizza is small.

play29:16

You don't really want it.

play29:18

But the marginal utility of cookies is high.

play29:20

You want many of them.

play29:21

So this is a big number.

play29:24

Now let's move to point B. Think about your next decision.

play29:28

Well, now, your marginal utility of pizza,

play29:32

if you were going to go from two to one slice of pizza,

play29:34

now pizza is worth a lot more than cookies.

play29:37

So now it gets smaller.

play29:39

So essentially, as you move along that indifference curve,

play29:42

because of this, you want-- because of diminishing

play29:44

marginal utility, it leads this issue

play29:46

of a diminishing marginal rate substitution, OK?

play29:50

So basically, as you move along the indifference curve,

play29:53

you're more and more willing to give up the good on the x-axis

play29:57

to get the good on the y-axis.

play29:58

As you move from the upper left to the lower

play30:00

right on that indifference map, figure 2-6,

play30:03

you're more you're more willing to give up

play30:06

the good on the x-axis to get the good on the y-axis.

play30:11

And what this implies is that indifference curves are--

play30:16

indifference curves are convex to the origin.

play30:21

Indifference curves are convex to the origin.

play30:24

That's very important.

play30:25

OK, let's see, they are not concave.

play30:28

They're either convex or straight.

play30:30

Let's say they're not concave to the origin, to be technical.

play30:34

Indifference curves can be linear.

play30:36

We'll come to that.

play30:37

But they can't be concave to the origin.

play30:39

Why?

play30:39

Well, let's look at the next figure, the last figure,

play30:42

figure 2-7.

play30:43

What would happen if indifference curves were

play30:45

concave to the origin?

play30:47

Then that would say, moving from one pizza--

play30:52

so now I've drawn a concave indifference curve.

play30:55

And with this indifference curve, moving from point A

play30:57

to point B leaves you indifferent.

play31:00

So you're happy to give up one slice of pizza

play31:03

to get one cookie.

play31:04

Starting with four slices of pizza and one cookie,

play31:07

you were happy to give up one slice of pizza

play31:10

to get one cookie.

play31:12

Now, starting from two and three,

play31:15

you're now willing to give up two slices of pizza

play31:17

to get one cookie.

play31:19

What does that violate?

play31:20

Why does that not make sense?

play31:22

Yeah.

play31:23

AUDIENCE: Law of diminishing marginal returns?

play31:25

JONATHAN GRUBER: Yeah, law of diminishing marginal utility.

play31:27

Here, you were happy to have one slice of pizza

play31:30

to get one cookie.

play31:31

Now you are willing to have two slices of pizza

play31:33

to get one cookie, even though you have

play31:33

less pizza and more cookies.

play31:35

That can't be right.

play31:37

As you have less pizza and more cookies, cookies--

play31:39

pizza should become more valuable, not less valuable,

play31:42

and cookies should become less valuable, not more valuable.

play31:45

So a concave to the origin indifference

play31:47

curve would violate the principle

play31:49

of diminishing marginal utility and diminishing marginal rate

play31:51

of substitution, OK?

play31:53

Yeah.

play31:54

AUDIENCE: What if it's like something like trading cards?

play31:56

JONATHAN GRUBER: OK.

play31:57

AUDIENCE: I mean, I mean, as you get more trading cards,

play32:01

you have-- you're already made a complete set.

play32:04

JONATHAN GRUBER: That's very interesting.

play32:06

So in some sense, what that is saying

play32:09

is that your utility function is really over sets.

play32:11

You're saying your utility functions

play32:12

isn't over trading cards.

play32:13

It's over sets.

play32:15

So basically, that's what's sort of a bit--

play32:19

you know, our models are flexible.

play32:21

One way is to say they're loose.

play32:23

Another way is to say they're flexible.

play32:25

But one of the challenges you'll face on this course

play32:28

is thinking about what is the decision set over which I'm

play32:31

writing my utility function?

play32:32

You're saying it's sets, not trading cards.

play32:34

So that's why it happens.

play32:37

Other questions?

play32:37

Good question.

play32:38

Yeah, at the back.

play32:39

AUDIENCE: What about like addictive things, where like,

play32:41

the more you have it, the more you want to buy?

play32:43

JONATHAN GRUBER: Yeah, that's a really relishing question.

play32:45

I spent a lot of my research life, actually--

play32:48

I did a lot of research for a number of years

play32:50

on thinking about how you properly

play32:51

model addictive decisions like smoking.

play32:54

Addictive decisions like smoking,

play32:56

essentially, it really is that your utility

play33:00

function itself shifts as you get more addictive.

play33:04

It's not that your marginal utility--

play33:06

the next cigarette is still worth

play33:07

less than the first cigarette.

play33:09

It's just that as you get more addicted,

play33:10

that first cigarette gets worth more and more to you.

play33:13

So when you wake up in the morning feeling crappy,

play33:15

that first cigarette still does more for you

play33:17

than the second cigarette.

play33:18

It's just, the next day you wake up feeling crappier, OK?

play33:22

So we model addiction as something

play33:23

where essentially, each day, cigarettes

play33:27

do less and less for you.

play33:28

You get essentially adjusted to new-- you habituate

play33:30

to higher levels.

play33:32

And this is why I do a lot of work-- you know, this is why,

play33:34

unfortunately, we saw last year, the number--

play33:36

the highest number of deaths from accidental

play33:38

overdose in US history.

play33:39

72,000 people died from drug overdoses last year, more than

play33:42

ever died in traffic accidents in our nation's history, OK?

play33:46

Why?

play33:47

Because people get habituated to certain levels,

play33:49

and they get habituated to certain levels.

play33:51

So people get hooked on Oxycontin.

play33:53

They get habituated to a certain level.

play33:55

They maybe switch to heroin, and they

play33:57

habituate to a certain level.

play33:58

And now there's this thing called fentanyl,

play34:00

which is a synthetic opioid brought over from China,

play34:02

which is incredibly powerful.

play34:04

And dealers are mixing the fentanyl in with the heroin.

play34:07

And the people shoot up, not realizing--

play34:09

at their habituated level-- not realizing

play34:11

they have this dangerous substance,

play34:12

and they overdose and die.

play34:14

And that's because they've got habituated to high levels.

play34:16

They don't realize they're getting a different product.

play34:17

So it's not about not diminishing marginal utility.

play34:19

It's about different-- underlying different products.

play34:22

All right?

play34:23

Other questions?

play34:25

Sorry for that depressing note, but it's

play34:27

important to be thinking about that.

play34:28

That's why, once again, we're the dismal science.

play34:30

We have to think about these things.

play34:31

OK, now, let's come to a great example

play34:35

that I hope you've wondered about,

play34:36

and maybe you've already figured out in your life,

play34:38

but I hope you've at least stopped

play34:40

and wondered about, which is the prices

play34:43

of different sizes of goods, in a convenience store, say.

play34:48

OK, take Starbucks.

play34:51

You can get a tall iced coffee for 2.25,

play34:55

or the next size, whatever the hell they call it, bigger, OK?

play34:58

You can get, for 70 more cents--

play35:01

so 2.25, and you can double it for 70 more cents.

play35:05

Or take McDonald's.

play35:06

A small drink is $1.22 at the local McDonald's, but for 50

play35:11

more cents, you can double the size, OK?

play35:14

What's going on here?

play35:16

Why did they give you twice as much liquid,

play35:19

or if you go for ice cream, it's the same thing.

play35:21

Why do they give you twice as much for much less than twice

play35:24

as much money?

play35:26

What's going on?

play35:26

Yeah.

play35:28

AUDIENCE: Since your marginal utility is diminishing

play35:31

as you have more coffee available to you,

play35:34

you're willing to pay less for it,

play35:36

so they make the additional coffee cheaper.

play35:39

JONATHAN GRUBER: Exactly.

play35:40

That's a great way to explain it.

play35:41

The point is it's all about diminishing marginal utility.

play35:45

OK, when you come in to McDonald's on a hot day,

play35:47

you are desperate for that soda, but you're not

play35:50

as desperate have twice as much soda.

play35:52

You'd like it.

play35:53

You probably want to pay more for it,

play35:54

but you don't like it nearly as much as that first bit of soda.

play35:58

So those prices simply reflects the market's reaction

play36:01

to understanding diminishing marginal utility.

play36:04

Now, we haven't even talked about the supply

play36:06

side of the market yet.

play36:07

I'm not getting to how providers make decisions.

play36:09

That's a much deeper issue.

play36:10

I'm just saying that this is diminishing marginal utility

play36:13

in action, how it works in the market,

play36:15

and that's why you see this, OK?

play36:18

So basically, what you see is that that first bite of ice

play36:23

cream, for example, is worth more,

play36:25

and that's why the ice cream that's twice as big

play36:27

doesn't cost twice as much.

play36:30

Now, so basically, what this means

play36:33

is, if you think about our demand and supply model,

play36:37

on a hot day, or any day, the demand for the first 16 ounces

play36:43

is higher than the demand for the second 16 ounces.

play36:48

But the cost of producing 16 ounces is the same.

play36:51

So let's think about this.

play36:52

It's always risky when I try to draw a graph on the board,

play36:55

but let's bear with me.

play36:56

OK, so let's say we've got a simple supply and demand model.

play36:59

You have this supply function for soda,

play37:03

and let's assume it's roughly flat.

play37:05

OK, let's assume sort of the cost the firm proceeds

play37:08

within some range.

play37:09

The firm-- basically, every incremental 16 ounces

play37:12

costs them the same.

play37:14

So that's sort of their supply curve.

play37:16

And then you have some demand curve, OK?

play37:19

You have some demand curve which is downward sloping, OK,

play37:22

and they set some price.

play37:24

And this is the demand for 16 ounces.

play37:27

Now, what's the demand for the next 16 ounces, OK?

play37:33

Yeah, this isn't going to work.

play37:34

We have to have an upward-sloping supply curve.

play37:35

Sorry about that.

play37:36

We have a slightly upward sloping supply curve, OK?

play37:39

Now we have the demand for the next--

play37:41

so here's your price.

play37:43

Here's your $1.22, OK?

play37:47

Now, you say, "Well, what's my demand when I sell 32 ounces?"

play37:52

Well, it turns out demand doesn't

play37:53

shift out twice as much.

play37:54

It just shifts out a little bit more.

play37:56

So you can only charge $1.72 for the next 16 ounces.

play37:59

Probably, if you want to go to the big--

play38:01

if you go to 7-Eleven, where you can get sizes up to, you know,

play38:04

as big as your house, OK--

play38:06

they keep these curves keep getting closer and closer

play38:08

to each other.

play38:09

So those price increments get smaller and smaller.

play38:12

And that's why you can get the monster, you know,

play38:14

ginormous Gulp at 7-Eleven--

play38:16

is really just not that different from the price

play38:19

of getting the small little mini size, OK,

play38:22

because of diminishing marginal utility.

play38:25

All right, and so that's how the market--

play38:27

that's essentially how we can take this abstract concept,

play38:31

this sort of crazy math, and turn it

play38:33

into literally what you see in the store you walk into, OK?

play38:36

Questions about that?

play38:38

Yeah.

play38:40

AUDIENCE: So how does this [? place ?] [INAUDIBLE],,

play38:45

like if for example, you wanted to buy a snack that you were

play38:48

going to have for breakfast every day--

play38:50

JONATHAN GRUBER: Awesome.

play38:51

Awesome question.

play38:52

AUDIENCE: And then every single day,

play38:53

it was going to be your first granola bar, right?

play38:55

So I think that it's going to diminish every single time,

play39:01

but it's still cheaper to buy in bulk

play39:03

than it would be to buy a single granola bar every single time.

play39:05

JONATHAN GRUBER: Great, great question.

play39:07

Yeah?

play39:07

AUDIENCE: I think that has more to do with packaging cost

play39:10

than marginal utility.

play39:11

JONATHAN GRUBER: Well, I mean, the risk

play39:13

of my going to this model is, once we get nonlinear,

play39:16

the order we do things in this class,

play39:17

we have to start talking about supply

play39:18

factors I want to talk to.

play39:19

But there's two answers.

play39:21

One is packaging efficiencies.

play39:23

But the other is, if you actually go to Costco

play39:27

and look at their prices, for many things,

play39:29

they're not actually better than the supermarket.

play39:31

So actually, the price of buying the giant like,

play39:34

8,000 bars of granola is actually not that much more--

play39:40

not that much less than 1,000 time buying eight granola bars.

play39:45

It's less, but it's not nearly as much less of these examples

play39:48

as sodas in McDonald's, which is exactly your point.

play39:51

Utility diminishes less, so they don't

play39:54

want to charge as much less for multiple packages.

play39:58

So you can actually-- if you compare

play39:59

the gap in perishable product pricing by size,

play40:02

it's much larger than the gap in nonperishable pricing by size.

play40:05

Great point.

play40:06

Yeah.

play40:07

AUDIENCE: Is there also just like a different time

play40:09

frame to which the utility starts

play40:10

diminishing for every product?

play40:12

Because you gave the example of soda, but it's like,

play40:15

would that reset later in the day, if we wanted--

play40:17

were thirsty again, or--

play40:18

JONATHAN GRUBER: Awesome, and that

play40:20

is why they don't let you walk back in with the same cup

play40:22

and refill it, right?

play40:23

That's exactly right, and that comes to this point.

play40:26

It's sort of like it's nonperishable

play40:27

as you get longer apart.

play40:31

But you know, it's all just really interesting.

play40:33

So at Fenway, OK, you can get--

play40:36

you get like a regular sized soda, it's like crazy.

play40:39

It's like $6.

play40:40

Then for like $8, you get a big soda.

play40:43

Then for $10, you get a refillable big soda, OK?

play40:47

Now, the question is, can you bring that refillable soda back

play40:49

to additional games?

play40:51

Technically not, but I do.

play40:54

[LAUGHING]

play40:55

And basically they sort of understand--

play40:58

so this interesting question of sort

play41:00

of the perishability of things and how that's going

play41:02

to affect things going on.

play41:04

It's a really-- it's an interesting question.

play41:07

Other comments?

play41:08

OK, I'm going to stop there.

play41:09

Those are great comments.

play41:11

Thanks everyone for participating.

play41:12

And we will come back next time and talk about the sad reality

play41:14

that we haven't won the lottery, and we

play41:16

have limited amounts of money.

Rate This
β˜…
β˜…
β˜…
β˜…
β˜…

5.0 / 5 (0 votes)

Related Tags
Economics 101Demand CurveSupply ModelConsumer ChoiceUtility FunctionIndifference CurvesMarginal UtilityBudget ConstraintEconomic TheoryMarket BehaviorConsumer Preferences