Fisheries Economics & Policy: Maximum Economic Yield

Conservation Strategy Fund
20 Nov 201415:40

Summary

TLDRThe video explains the dynamics of fish population and how overfishing impacts sustainable catches. It uses the example of the Grand Banks Cod collapse to show how increased fishing effort doesn't always mean higher catches and is a sign of declining fish stocks. The video models fish population growth, carrying capacity, and introduces the concept of maximum sustainable yield (MSY). It then discusses economic aspects like maximizing profits (economic rent) while maintaining sustainability. The video ends by addressing how open-access fisheries lead to overfishing and suggests a need for better management strategies to optimize economic and ecological outcomes.

Takeaways

  • 🎣 Increasing fishing effort without a corresponding increase in catches is a clear sign of declining fish populations.
  • 🐟 The Grand Banks Cod was overfished due to ignoring scientific warnings, resulting in a 20-year fishing ban to help the population recover.
  • 📉 Fishing quotas need to account for the natural growth rate of fish populations to avoid overfishing and depletion.
  • 🔄 Fish population growth is slow at low and high population levels, with the fastest growth occurring at mid-level populations.
  • ⚖️ Sustainable fishing happens when the amount of fish taken equals the population's growth rate, maintaining a balance.
  • 🛑 Overfishing occurs when the catch exceeds the fish population's growth, leading to a decline in fish numbers over time.
  • 📊 The goal is to set fishing quotas that maximize economic rent (profit) while ensuring sustainability.
  • 💰 Maximum economic yield occurs when fishing effort is optimized to generate the most profit without depleting the population.
  • ⛔ Open access fisheries, where multiple fishermen compete, often lead to overfishing as each fisherman tries to maximize personal gain.
  • 🤝 Cooperation and regulation are needed in fisheries to ensure sustainable fishing practices and prevent stock collapse.

Q & A

  • What are the indicators of a declining fish population despite stable catches?

    -If the number of boats, the size of the boats, and the technology used for fishing are all increasing, but the total catch remains the same, this suggests that the fish population is likely declining. Increased effort without a rise in catch is a clear sign of an unhealthy fish stock.

  • What happened to the Grand Banks cod population off the eastern coast of Canada?

    -The Grand Banks cod population declined due to overfishing. Despite scientists warning about the decreasing fish stock, policymakers focused on stable catch levels and ignored the warning signs. Eventually, the population collapsed, and a fishing ban has been in place for over 20 years.

  • What is 'carrying capacity' in the context of fish populations?

    -Carrying capacity refers to the maximum number of fish that an environment can support. Once the population reaches this level, the growth rate slows because food, space, and other resources become limited, balancing the birth and death rates.

  • How does population growth rate change as fish populations increase?

    -At low populations, growth is slow because there are fewer fish reproducing. As the population grows, the growth rate increases, but once the population nears the carrying capacity, the growth rate slows again due to limited resources.

  • What is the 'maximum sustainable yield' (MSY), and why is it important in fisheries management?

    -MSY is the largest amount of fish that can be sustainably harvested without depleting the population. Fishing beyond this point leads to a decline in the fish population. MSY is important because it helps determine how much fish can be caught while ensuring the long-term survival of the stock.

  • Why is aiming for the 'maximum economic yield' (MEY) better than aiming for the MSY?

    -While MSY focuses on maximizing the number of fish caught, MEY aims to maximize economic profit by balancing revenue and costs. MEY allows for higher rent (profit) with less fishing effort, preserving the population and making the fishery more resilient.

  • How does fishing effort impact both population and revenue in the long term?

    -As fishing effort increases, the fish population decreases, which in turn reduces the overall revenue generated from the fishery. More effort may initially result in higher catches, but over time, diminishing fish populations reduce productivity and profitability.

  • What happens under an 'open access' scenario in a fishery with multiple boats?

    -In an open access fishery, multiple fishermen compete for the same resource, leading to overfishing. Each individual fisherman focuses on maximizing their own profit without considering the overall population health, causing more boats to enter the fishery until the total revenue equals the total costs, eliminating rent and overexploiting the resource.

  • How do marginal costs and marginal benefits affect a fisherman's decision-making?

    -Fishermen continue to fish until the marginal cost of fishing (e.g., fuel, labor) equals the marginal revenue (the profit from an additional catch). When costs exceed revenue, it is no longer profitable to continue fishing.

  • What is the danger of continuing to fish past the maximum sustainable yield (MSY)?

    -Fishing beyond the MSY reduces the fish population below sustainable levels, leading to a decline in catches over time. If unchecked, this can result in population collapse, as seen with the Grand Banks cod, forcing drastic measures like long-term fishing bans.

Outlines

00:00

🐟 Declining Fish Populations: Warning Signs and Historical Example

The paragraph discusses the steady decline in fish catches despite increased fishing efforts through technological advancements. This is a clear sign of declining fish populations, as illustrated by the Grand Banks Cod collapse off the coast of Canada. Policymakers ignored scientific warnings, leading to overfishing and the eventual collapse of the cod population. The ban on cod fishing, which has lasted over 20 years, highlights the dangers of increasing fishing effort without a corresponding increase in catches.

05:00

📉 Modeling Fish Population Growth and Sustainable Fishing

This paragraph introduces a basic model of fish population growth over time, explaining how reproduction rates vary depending on population levels. When populations are low or high, growth is slow, while moderate populations foster faster growth. The paragraph highlights the concept of 'carrying capacity' and explains how sustainable fishing can be modeled by determining what portion of the population's growth can be harvested without causing long-term decline.

10:02

⚖️ Sustainable Yield and Fishery Equilibrium

Here, the focus shifts to determining how much fish can be caught sustainably, using population growth data. It explains how overfishing beyond the population's growth rate leads to decline, while staying below it allows the population to recover. The 'maximum sustainable yield' is introduced as the point at which the most fish can be harvested without lowering the population. However, the paragraph also stresses the importance of caution and aiming for a slightly lower catch for added safety.

15:04

💰 Maximizing Economic Rent in Fisheries

This section emphasizes that the goal of fisheries is not only to catch the maximum number of fish but also to maximize economic rent (or profit). By adjusting the graph to focus on revenue from fish catches, it becomes clear that as fish populations decline, more fishing effort is required, and costs rise. The relationship between fishing effort and population is explained, with the aim of maintaining high revenue while minimizing effort to sustain fish populations and economic profitability.

📊 Balancing Fishing Effort for Maximum Economic Yield

The concept of 'maximum economic yield' (MEY) is explored, which aims to maximize profit by balancing fishing effort with sustainable fish populations. MEY occurs when the difference between revenue and costs is greatest. This is shown to be a better long-term strategy than catching the maximum sustainable yield, as it leaves the fish population healthier and more resilient. It’s also highlighted that real-world fishermen don’t necessarily stop fishing at MEY, leading to potential overexploitation.

⛴ Open Access Fisheries and Overexploitation

The problem of 'open access' fisheries, where multiple fishermen compete for the same fish stock, is described. While an individual fisherman may stop fishing at the maximum economic yield, multiple fishermen, driven by competition, may continue fishing past this point. This leads to decreased overall rent (profit) and more effort for the same or fewer fish. The paragraph warns that open access can lead to the collapse of fish populations as competition drives more effort, even when it’s no longer profitable.

📉 The Race to the Bottom in Fisheries

Continuing the discussion on open access fisheries, this paragraph explains how competition drives fishermen to continue fishing even when it's no longer profitable. The introduction of additional boats reduces overall rent, and overfishing becomes inevitable until total revenue equals total cost, leaving no rent. The system is inefficient, as the same amount of fish could be caught with less effort and more profit under a more coordinated approach.

📈 Moving Towards Maximum Economic Yield and Sustainable Practices

The final paragraph outlines the need for collective action and better management strategies to encourage fishing at the maximum economic yield, which preserves fish populations and maximizes profit. It introduces the next part of the series, which will address challenges in the fishing industry and explore methods to structure fisheries for long-term sustainability, higher rent, and healthier fish populations.

Mindmap

Keywords

💡Fish Population

The term 'fish population' refers to the number of fish within a specific area or ecosystem. In the video, it is central to discussions about overfishing, sustainable fishing practices, and the decline of species like the Grand Bank's Cod. Understanding the population dynamics helps in determining sustainable fishing quotas to prevent depletion.

💡Fishing Effort

Fishing effort represents the amount of resources (boats, technology, time) invested in fishing. The video highlights how increasing fishing effort without a corresponding rise in catches indicates declining fish populations. It also explores the relationship between effort and fish stock, showing that excessive effort can lead to stock collapse.

💡Overfishing

Overfishing occurs when fish are caught at a faster rate than they can reproduce, leading to population decline. The video uses the example of the Grand Bank's Cod, where overfishing and failure to act led to a significant collapse of the fish stock, prompting a fishing ban for over 20 years.

💡Carrying Capacity

Carrying capacity refers to the maximum population size of a species that an environment can support without degradation. The video illustrates how fish populations grow until they reach their ecosystem's carrying capacity, after which growth slows due to limitations like food and habitat. Managing catches requires understanding this concept to avoid overexploitation.

💡Maximum Sustainable Yield (MSY)

MSY is the largest amount of fish that can be harvested from a population without causing long-term depletion. The video explains how exceeding this yield leads to declining populations, while taking less allows the population to grow and reach equilibrium. It’s a key concept for setting fishing quotas sustainably.

💡Economic Rent

Economic rent in the context of the video refers to the profit made from fishing, defined as the difference between revenue and costs. The goal is to maximize this rent sustainably. The video highlights that fishing should aim to maximize economic rent over time, rather than just catching the maximum number of fish.

💡Equilibrium Catch

The equilibrium catch is the amount of fish that can be harvested without changing the fish population over time. The video describes how catching at the equilibrium point allows for sustainable fishing practices, where the population remains stable and avoids overfishing or collapse.

💡Fishing Quota

A fishing quota is a regulatory limit on how much fish can be caught to prevent overfishing. The video emphasizes the need for setting quotas based on ecological data to ensure the long-term sustainability of fish populations and maintain balance within the ecosystem.

💡Marginal Cost and Marginal Revenue

Marginal cost is the cost of catching one more unit of fish, while marginal revenue is the income generated from catching that additional fish. The video explains how fishermen make decisions based on these margins, and how overfishing occurs when marginal costs start exceeding marginal revenues.

💡Open Access Fisheries

Open access fisheries are fishing grounds that are not regulated by quotas or limits, allowing unrestricted access to fishermen. The video explains that this lack of regulation leads to excessive fishing effort, which can drive fish populations down to unsustainable levels, leading to a collapse in both fish stocks and economic rent.

Highlights

Catches are steadily falling, likely due to overfishing, and even though the effort and technology in fishing increase, catches remain the same, indicating a declining fish population.

The Grand Banks Cod in Canada was overfished, leading to a ban on fishing for over 20 years due to a critically low population.

Increased fishing effort without increased catches is a clear sign of an unhealthy fish population.

The fish population growth rate is low when the population is either very high or very low, but grows fastest at an intermediate population level.

When fishing catches exceed the natural growth rate of a fish population, the population will decline.

Taking an amount of fish below the sustainable growth line allows the population to grow, ensuring future catches.

The maximum sustainable yield is the highest amount of fish that can be caught without reducing the population, but aiming for economic rent can provide a more sustainable, long-term approach.

Economic rent maximizes profit for fishers by balancing revenue and cost, which often results in catching fewer fish than the maximum sustainable yield.

Fishing at the maximum economic yield results in a healthier fish population and more resilience to external stress.

Under Open Access, fishers increase their effort until total costs equal total revenue, which leads to overfishing and reduced profits.

Fishing efforts can continue even when total revenue decreases because individual fishers focus on their own share rather than total fishery health.

Open Access fisheries lead to overexploitation because fishers compete for the largest share of the catch, reducing overall economic rent.

At maximum economic yield, total rent is highest, and fish populations are healthier and more resilient.

Groups of fishers require incentives to cooperate in order to avoid overfishing and maximize rent at a sustainable level.

The series will explore further challenges facing modern fisheries and potential solutions to structure them for sustainable and profitable fishing.

Transcripts

play00:01

okay let's say we have a stock of fish a

play00:04

population of fish and we see that the

play00:06

catches are steadily falling every year

play00:08

and it's probably from fishing too much

play00:10

or maybe the catch isn't falling it's

play00:13

staying about the same from year to year

play00:15

but we notice that the number of boats

play00:16

on the stock is increasing and the size

play00:19

of the boats is increasing and the

play00:21

technology they're using is becoming

play00:23

more advanced the amount of effort that

play00:25

seems to be going into fishing is

play00:26

increasing but the catches are not if

play00:29

there's more effort being being put into

play00:30

fishing but there's not more fish being

play00:32

caught it's a pretty clear sign that the

play00:34

population is probably declining this

play00:37

exact thing happened to the Grand bank's

play00:38

Cod off the eastern coast of Canada the

play00:41

scientists who monitored the fish

play00:42

population calculated the fish stock was

play00:44

on the decline but the policymakers saw

play00:46

that there were still high catches from

play00:47

the fisherman and thought scientists

play00:50

with their math and their hipster

play00:52

glasses but the stock was indeed

play00:54

overfished and the catches weren't

play00:56

changing because of the increased

play00:57

technology because nothing was done the

play01:00

population continued to decline and

play01:02

eventually the catches did too as of now

play01:04

there's been a ban on fishing Cod for

play01:06

over 20 years because the population has

play01:08

been so low increasing effort without

play01:10

increasing catches is a sign of an

play01:12

unhealthy population anyways it may be

play01:14

clear that fishing needs to decrease on

play01:16

a particular stock but to what degree in

play01:19

this video we're going to look at what

play01:20

we should be aiming for in a fishing

play01:23

quota first let's try to model how fish

play01:25

populations behave let's say this line

play01:27

represents fish population this axis is

play01:29

population and this axis is time or

play01:32

something let's say there's not a lot of

play01:33

fish in the beginning so we're down here

play01:35

they're going to reproduce but at first

play01:38

their population isn't going to rise

play01:39

that fast because there's not a lot of

play01:41

fish reproducing as their population

play01:43

increases more and more fish reach

play01:44

sexual maturity and the population Rises

play01:47

faster but then growth slows down as

play01:49

food and habitat space become scarce and

play01:51

then eventually the death rate equals

play01:53

the birth rate this is the highest

play01:54

population this particular environment

play01:56

can fit the carrying capacity in reality

play01:59

ecosystems are Dynamic and this level is

play02:01

always always changing for example if

play02:03

some food sources are depleted or the

play02:04

fish find other food sources or if they

play02:06

move around and this is no small effect

play02:08

and when setting quotas we can't ignore

play02:10

that but for our model here we're just

play02:12

going to treat it as constant so what

play02:14

this is showing is that down here when

play02:15

the population is low the growth rate is

play02:17

low and also when the population is high

play02:19

the growth rate is low somewhere in the

play02:21

middle is where the fast growth is

play02:23

happening okay let's take this same

play02:25

information but model the population

play02:27

growth rate as it changes with the

play02:29

population assuming the population is

play02:31

the only thing that affects the growth

play02:32

rate so when the population is zero the

play02:34

growth rate is zero because there's no

play02:36

fish to reproduce at low populations the

play02:38

growth rate is low but as the population

play02:40

Rises then reproduction Rises at some

play02:43

point food and habitat are starting to

play02:44

limit growth reproduction rates are

play02:46

still high but they're starting to

play02:47

decline the growth rate slows and slows

play02:50

until the carrying capacity is reached

play02:52

okay so this is basically showing the

play02:53

same thing as this other graph when the

play02:55

population is in the middle the growth

play02:57

is fast when the population is low or

play02:59

when it's it's high the growth is slower

play03:01

but what this graph can show us is what

play03:03

amounts of fish we can take and how it

play03:05

affects the population if the fish

play03:07

population was here then the fish is

play03:08

growing by this amount so we know we can

play03:11

take that amount and by next time the

play03:13

population wouldn't have changed if the

play03:15

population was still here but we took

play03:17

below that line then next period the

play03:19

population would be greater if we keep

play03:20

taking that amount the population will

play03:22

grow and grow and grow until it reaches

play03:24

here now we're at the growth line for

play03:26

this fish if we take this much again the

play03:28

population isn't going to change if the

play03:30

population were here but we took this

play03:31

much fish then we're taking more than

play03:33

that period's amount of growth and next

play03:35

time the fish population will be lower

play03:37

if we still take that much the next

play03:39

period then it will be lower and lower

play03:40

and lower what I'm calling the period

play03:42

will depend entirely on the Ecology of

play03:44

the fish and requires a bit more insight

play03:46

for Simplicity we're just sort of

play03:48

assuming that it's the growth in between

play03:50

fishing seasons and it only depends on

play03:52

the population of the fish if you take a

play03:54

catch below the line the population Will

play03:56

Rise by next period if you take above

play03:58

the line the population will fall by

play04:00

Next Period catches along the line won't

play04:03

change the population so if you take an

play04:05

amount of fish in these areas here the

play04:07

catch is sustainable the population will

play04:09

change but only until it reaches the

play04:11

line in this way the line is an

play04:13

equilibrium for the catches but if the

play04:15

amount of fish is taken in this area

play04:17

then the population will decline keep

play04:19

taking in those areas and the population

play04:21

might collapse so it's always safer to

play04:23

be fishing when the population is high

play04:25

if the population is low we'll want to

play04:27

try to take an amount from below the

play04:29

line so the population is safely given

play04:31

Room to Grow okay so based on this how

play04:34

much should we be taking well of the

play04:36

catches along the line this point here

play04:39

allows us to take the maximum amount of

play04:41

fish each period this is the maximum

play04:43

sustainable yield taking any higher will

play04:45

result in a declining population so we

play04:48

could try to take a little bit less when

play04:49

the population is good just for safety I

play04:52

think this was actually an old basis for

play04:53

setting fishing quotas but it's pretty

play04:55

shallow I mean maybe it would be fine if

play04:58

our goal was to take take as much fish

play05:00

out of the water as fast as we can but

play05:02

that's not our goal our goal or rather

play05:04

the fisherman's goal and Fisher women

play05:07

who will hereby be referred to

play05:08

collectively as fishermen fishermen will

play05:10

want to make as much money as they can

play05:12

for as long as they can so our goal is

play05:14

to maximize the economic rent from

play05:16

fishing and to do it sustainably for as

play05:19

long as possible if you're new to the

play05:20

term economic rent don't worry about it

play05:23

just think of it as profit for now the

play05:25

difference between the costs and the

play05:26

revenue there are some important

play05:28

differences between rent and profit

play05:30

which is why we're bringing it up but

play05:31

for here if you just think of it as

play05:33

profit you'll do just fine but I'm going

play05:35

to call it rent anyway so let's change

play05:37

this graph to reflect that we're trying

play05:39

to maximize the amount of money made

play05:41

instead of looking at what amount of

play05:42

fish is taken from period to period

play05:44

sustainably let's change this to what

play05:46

amount of money can be made sustainably

play05:48

from period to period the line changes

play05:50

from what catches are sustainable to

play05:52

what earnings are sustainable we're

play05:54

going to keep the line the same shape

play05:55

you can look at it like it's just

play05:57

whatever fish was caught was then sold

play05:59

and the price of fish isn't ever

play06:01

changing okay now this is a revenue

play06:03

curve the total revenue curve from the

play06:05

amount of fish caught for the bottom

play06:07

axis we have population but we're

play06:09

assuming the population is only changing

play06:10

because of what we're doing that is how

play06:12

much effort we're putting into fishing

play06:14

so let's track that instead and change

play06:16

this access to fishing effort this is

play06:19

how the population will be experienced

play06:21

by the fishing industry on a cost and

play06:22

revenue basis if the population is low

play06:25

then they have to put more effort into

play06:27

finding and catching fish because

play06:29

there's L Fish to find there's less fish

play06:31

in every net effort is a term that

play06:33

refers to a few things it could refer to

play06:35

how long people are fishing or how many

play06:37

people are fishing or how advanced the

play06:39

fishing gear is it's about how much

play06:41

equipment is on the fish stock so more

play06:43

boats fishing more time spent fishing

play06:45

more Advanced Equipment more efficient

play06:47

techniques are all increasing the amount

play06:49

of effort while money and fish catch

play06:52

were directly related effort and

play06:54

population are actually inversely

play06:55

related as the population decreases more

play06:58

fishing effort is required to find out

play07:00

where they are and there's less fish in

play07:01

every net or we could look at it like

play07:03

the more effort put into fishing the

play07:05

lower the population will be but we want

play07:06

low effort over here and have the effort

play07:08

increasing so we're going to switch the

play07:10

axis so that high fish population is

play07:12

here and low population is over here as

play07:14

fishing effort increases so look at it

play07:17

like this we've come to a new stock the

play07:18

population is high because we haven't

play07:20

touched it yet and the more effort

play07:21

that's put into fishing the lower the

play07:23

overall population gets okay so now this

play07:25

graph is what are the sustainable

play07:27

earnings when certain amounts of fishing

play07:29

effort are put in let's say we come to a

play07:31

new stock at the beginning when the

play07:32

population is at carrying capacity the

play07:34

equilibrium catch is zero right the

play07:37

population is as high as it can be

play07:39

there's no net growth so there's no

play07:41

amount of fish that we can take without

play07:42

affecting the population if we put in

play07:44

some effort the equilibrium catch

play07:46

increases we freed up some room for the

play07:49

fish to grow and the growth rate

play07:50

increases so the equilibrium catch

play07:52

increases but it's still low the high

play07:54

population is limiting the growth rate

play07:56

of the fish as we put in more effort we

play07:59

keep freeing up room for the fish and

play08:01

the growth rate increases until it

play08:03

reaches this point the maximum

play08:05

sustainable yield coming up to this

play08:07

point the population was still limiting

play08:09

growth a little bit but after this point

play08:11

it's the fact that the population is

play08:13

lower and there's less fish reproducing

play08:14

that's limiting growth and this trend

play08:16

continues until there's no more fish

play08:18

reproducing keep in mind we changed this

play08:21

axis from population to effort with the

play08:23

old graph when we caught a certain

play08:25

amount of fish the population changed

play08:27

and we could sort of track how the

play08:28

population changed when certain amounts

play08:30

of fish were taken season to season but

play08:32

we can't do that with this graph there's

play08:34

no population anymore for example let's

play08:37

say we come to a new stock and we put in

play08:39

a ton of effort there's tons of boats

play08:40

fishing on it is the total revenue going

play08:42

to be this measly amount of money well

play08:44

no that first season they're going to

play08:46

catch a lot and the industry will have a

play08:48

high total revenue the relationship

play08:50

between effort and revenue for one

play08:52

season would look more like this the

play08:54

more effort you put in the more fish you

play08:55

catch until there's no more fish to

play08:57

catch here you can put in more effort

play08:59

but you're not going to make any more

play09:00

money but with this graph when we refer

play09:03

to this amount of effort being put in we

play09:05

mean after many seasons and an

play09:07

equilibrium has been reached remember

play09:09

that previous chart if we try to catch

play09:11

this amount the population will change

play09:13

until the catch equals the growth rate

play09:16

along the line This level showing the

play09:18

amount of fish that's taken is kind of

play09:20

like the effort kind of when we look at

play09:22

this graph we're assuming an equilibrium

play09:24

like that has already been reached this

play09:25

is after many seasons okay okay to

play09:28

determine the economic rent we need to

play09:30

know what the costs are let's pretend

play09:32

there's only one person fishing on this

play09:33

stock and fishing effort will measure

play09:35

just as the amount of time they're

play09:37

spending fishing the first week of

play09:39

fishing costs this much the second week

play09:41

costs this much the third well each week

play09:44

costs the same the total cost line is

play09:46

going to be a straight line we're just

play09:48

assuming additional units of effort

play09:50

extra weeks of fishing always costs the

play09:52

same amount okay to maximize economic

play09:54

rent we want the spot where the

play09:56

difference between the revenue and the

play09:57

costs is greatest there is an equation

play09:59

to derive it personally I'm just going

play10:01

to eyeball it it is here we can fish

play10:05

more and make more total revenue but the

play10:07

cost will increase by more from that

play10:09

point so the total economic rent will

play10:12

actually go down that's no good compare

play10:14

that to if we were back here and we

play10:16

wanted to put in more effort the total

play10:18

revenue increases by more than the total

play10:20

cost so we should be putting in more

play10:21

effort we can be making additional rent

play10:24

this spot is the maximum economic yield

play10:27

it's the amount of effort where the rent

play10:28

is maximized at the maximum economic

play10:30

yield the catch will be sustainable the

play10:32

rent is high as it can be everyone's

play10:34

happy and note that the maximum economic

play10:36

yield is at a lower fish catch than the

play10:38

maximum sustainable yield even though

play10:40

we're catching less fish more rent is

play10:42

being generated and also the population

play10:44

is larger so it will be more resilient

play10:46

to other stresses but the problem is

play10:48

fishermen don't study a graph pick this

play10:50

point and say I'm going to fish with

play10:52

this amount of effort they live day by

play10:54

day year by year trying to maximize

play10:56

their personal rent so we need to look

play10:58

at this graph in a a different way let's

play11:00

look at it in steps to see how the

play11:01

fishermen are thinking we need to

play11:03

examine the marginal costs and marginal

play11:05

benefits let's say in between each of

play11:07

these lines is one week again we're

play11:09

still assuming this is one fisherman if

play11:10

the Fisher fishes for one week they'll

play11:12

make this much revenue and pay this much

play11:15

cost if the Fisher fishes for 2 weeks

play11:17

they're making this much revenue and

play11:18

paying this much in costs but the extra

play11:21

Revenue the marginal revenue from an

play11:23

extra week's catch is this amount the

play11:25

extra costs from an additional week is

play11:27

this amount the third week of fishing

play11:29

will give them this much additional

play11:31

total revenue and they'll have to pay

play11:33

this much additional total costs as I

play11:35

fill these in note here P the maximum

play11:38

sustainable yield the total revenue is

play11:40

actually going down they would be

play11:41

spending so many weeks on the stock that

play11:43

the population is getting to a point

play11:45

where additional effort is damaging the

play11:47

fish's productivity okay how many weeks

play11:49

is the Fisher going to fish they'll fish

play11:51

until the marginal revenue is no longer

play11:54

greater than the marginal costs when the

play11:56

extra week of fishing costs more than

play11:57

the money from the fish again eyeballing

play12:00

it it looks about here where the

play12:01

marginal revenue equals the marginal

play12:03

costs they could spend another week

play12:05

fishing but they wouldn't catch enough

play12:06

fish to cover the cost of gas and labor

play12:08

and whatever it's just not worth it so

play12:11

they'll stop interesting one person

play12:13

fishing alone will stop fishing at the

play12:15

maximum economic yield which is great

play12:17

and all but a stock of fish is almost

play12:20

never fished by one person okay so what

play12:22

happens when the stock of fish is under

play12:24

an Open Access scenario fished by

play12:26

multiple people they're going to be

play12:27

fishing with slightly different

play12:29

incentives so let's change this up we'll

play12:31

use the same chart but this time let's

play12:33

measure fishing effort as the number of

play12:35

boats on the water this will be just for

play12:37

Simplicity this will be the same effect

play12:39

whether we're talking about increasing

play12:41

technology or increasing amount of time

play12:43

they're each spending fishing any other

play12:45

effort measure the important thing is

play12:46

there are multiple people using the

play12:48

resource now one fisherman will stop at

play12:51

the maximum economic yield if he kept

play12:53

fishing he could make more money but not

play12:54

enough to cover those new costs it's the

play12:57

same thing with multiple boats and if

play12:59

the industry were acting as a single

play13:01

unit they wouldn't add any additional

play13:02

boats the additional catch doesn't cover

play13:05

the additional costs but the new boat

play13:07

doesn't see it that way they're not

play13:08

getting this amount of Revenue which

play13:10

wouldn't cover the costs right they're

play13:12

there with everyone else they share a

play13:14

total of the revenue of the industry the

play13:16

total number of fish caught and the

play13:18

revenue only increased by a little bit

play13:20

but they're not making decisions based

play13:21

on that they only see their share okay

play13:24

so an individual or a group acting as an

play13:26

individual will think does this extra

play13:28

effort make the whole Pi bigger no then

play13:30

screw it but working within a group

play13:32

that's not working together people will

play13:34

think does this extra effort make my

play13:36

slice bigger the individual has the

play13:38

opportunity to gain more by in essence

play13:40

trying to get a bigger portion of the

play13:42

pie so if we assume the fishermen always

play13:44

share an equal portion of the catch then

play13:46

they're each coming away with just the

play13:48

total revenue divided by the total

play13:50

number of boats okay so it's this line

play13:52

here in between each of these lines is

play13:54

no longer one week but the amount of

play13:56

effort that one boat puts in each boat

play13:58

makes the amount in revenue and spends

play14:00

this amount in costs okay so this was

play14:03

where an individual would stop fishing

play14:05

more effort means less rent but here the

play14:07

extra person coming in can earn some

play14:09

additional rent by basically taking a

play14:11

little bit of everyone else's but

play14:12

remember back there at the maximum

play14:14

economic yield was where rent was

play14:16

maximized we're only going down in rent

play14:18

by going forwards but people will keep

play14:20

entering the fishery because they don't

play14:21

see it that way even past this point

play14:23

when the total revenue is actually

play14:25

decreasing the new fishermen still see

play14:27

rent to earn people will keep keep

play14:29

entering the fishery until that is no

play14:30

longer the case that is here when the

play14:33

total revenue equals the total costs now

play14:35

when new boat won't enter the fishery

play14:37

they would buy a boat hire a crew and

play14:39

never find enough fish to cover those

play14:40

costs this is the amount of effort that

play14:42

a group under Open Access will put in at

play14:45

this point the total revenue equals the

play14:47

total costs and there's no rent being

play14:49

made there's less rent being made and in

play14:51

this case less fish being caught and

play14:53

significantly more effort being put in

play14:55

than back at the maximum economic yield

play14:58

also they could have caught the same

play14:59

amount over here for way less effort and

play15:01

way more rent and now we're potentially

play15:03

in a danger zone for collapse this is

play15:05

all less than ideal we want to be

play15:07

fishing back here at the maximum

play15:09

economic yield while one fisherman will

play15:11

stop there anyway a group needs extra

play15:13

incentive to cooperate and that's our

play15:16

next goal in the rest of this series

play15:17

we're going to look at a few more

play15:18

challenges facing fishing industries

play15:20

today and then what are some things we

play15:22

can do to try to structure a fishery so

play15:23

that people fish at the maximum economic

play15:25

yield where population is relatively

play15:27

healthy and the rent is

play15:30

[Music]

play15:39

high

Rate This

5.0 / 5 (0 votes)

Ähnliche Tags
Sustainable fishingOverfishingFishery managementEconomic rentMarine ecosystemsFishing quotasPopulation dynamicsEnvironmental impactFishermen economicsOpen access fishing
Benötigen Sie eine Zusammenfassung auf Englisch?